Skip to content

Latest commit

 

History

History
36 lines (22 loc) · 3.7 KB

VOTE-SWAPPING.md

File metadata and controls

36 lines (22 loc) · 3.7 KB

Vote Swapping - Simple Blind Ratio (SBR)

One of the core aspects of IBDD (Issue Based Direct Democracy) is the ability for voters to trade votes with each other. By this simple definition, there may be multiple variations of IBDD. In many of these variations, it is proposed to be achievable via 'political capital' (PC); a sort of currency/credit to overcome the 'coincidence of wants' obstacle. There is a multitude of ways that converting votes into political capital (and vice versa) may be achieved. This discussion will attempt to make the case for one, the Simple Blind Ratio.

The Simple Blind Ratio is 'blind' because voters don't know the price (in terms of political capital) of their vote (on a particular issue) until the allocated voting time has expired. The voter may choose one of 3 options when a new proposal for an issue is published for voting. These options include (1) Vote in favour of the proposal, (2) vote against the proposal OR (3) trade vote for political capital. When a voter opts to trade their vote, it is converted into political capital when the allocated voting time has expired. Note, votes will be automatically converted into political capital if the voter neglects to make a vote and is, therefore, the default option. Voters also have access to an additional option; (4) to trade their saved PC for shares in votes. The price of traded votes is determined by the simple ratio:

Vote price = Sum of all spent political capital / Sum of all traded votes

And is calculated after the allocated voting period has expired. The political capital obtained is then stored and may be used for future issues. In turn, the shares of votes that is obtained by an individual voter spending political capital is determined by:

Vote share = political capital spent by a voter / Vote price

The obtained vote share will then be allocate to the position (for or against) that was predetermined by the voter.

Outcomes:

  • A Simple Blind Ratio may be considered fair as the price of votes would be the same for all voters
  • It would be simple for voters/users to use
  • No price/value feedback loop: others need to decide what they are willing to lose
  • Voters would not be able to know the price of their vote and therefore not allowing them to match that price with how much they value a vote on a particular issue

The case for Flux

Is the Simple Blind Ratio the right variation of IBDD for Flux?

The main advantage of using an SBR is that it's simple. Usually, the more complex a system/product is to use, the less likely people are willing to engage with that product. By keeping it simple, the learning curve, for users, will be smaller allowing them to be quickly familiar with the system.

The advantage of the PC price being calculated and revealed after the allocated voting period has expired is that it would make it possible for all votes to have the same price for votes. On one end of the spectrum, if the price was predetermined, there would be a danger that the traded vote may not have the 'true market value'; in terms of supply and demand. On the other end, if the price is allowed to vary during the allocated voting period, some people may be at a disadvantage as they may not get the same opportunity as others to get the optimal price when trading their vote due to time, connectivity or personal restrictions. It is important in healthy democracies that we aim for equal voting opportunity across all voters. This sentiment should be extended to vote-swapping within IBDD's as well (open for debate).

Although an SBR version of IBDD does not allow voters to get the same price for a vote as what they value that vote, it is the same for everyone and therefore maintains equality.

You win some; you lose some.