forked from llorracc/BufferStockTheory
-
Notifications
You must be signed in to change notification settings - Fork 0
/
BufferStockTheory-NoAppendix.tex
1650 lines (1297 loc) · 138 KB
/
BufferStockTheory-NoAppendix.tex
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
61
62
63
64
65
66
67
68
69
70
71
72
73
74
75
76
77
78
79
80
81
82
83
84
85
86
87
88
89
90
91
92
93
94
95
96
97
98
99
100
101
102
103
104
105
106
107
108
109
110
111
112
113
114
115
116
117
118
119
120
121
122
123
124
125
126
127
128
129
130
131
132
133
134
135
136
137
138
139
140
141
142
143
144
145
146
147
148
149
150
151
152
153
154
155
156
157
158
159
160
161
162
163
164
165
166
167
168
169
170
171
172
173
174
175
176
177
178
179
180
181
182
183
184
185
186
187
188
189
190
191
192
193
194
195
196
197
198
199
200
201
202
203
204
205
206
207
208
209
210
211
212
213
214
215
216
217
218
219
220
221
222
223
224
225
226
227
228
229
230
231
232
233
234
235
236
237
238
239
240
241
242
243
244
245
246
247
248
249
250
251
252
253
254
255
256
257
258
259
260
261
262
263
264
265
266
267
268
269
270
271
272
273
274
275
276
277
278
279
280
281
282
283
284
285
286
287
288
289
290
291
292
293
294
295
296
297
298
299
300
301
302
303
304
305
306
307
308
309
310
311
312
313
314
315
316
317
318
319
320
321
322
323
324
325
326
327
328
329
330
331
332
333
334
335
336
337
338
339
340
341
342
343
344
345
346
347
348
349
350
351
352
353
354
355
356
357
358
359
360
361
362
363
364
365
366
367
368
369
370
371
372
373
374
375
376
377
378
379
380
381
382
383
384
385
386
387
388
389
390
391
392
393
394
395
396
397
398
399
400
401
402
403
404
405
406
407
408
409
410
411
412
413
414
415
416
417
418
419
420
421
422
423
424
425
426
427
428
429
430
431
432
433
434
435
436
437
438
439
440
441
442
443
444
445
446
447
448
449
450
451
452
453
454
455
456
457
458
459
460
461
462
463
464
465
466
467
468
469
470
471
472
473
474
475
476
477
478
479
480
481
482
483
484
485
486
487
488
489
490
491
492
493
494
495
496
497
498
499
500
501
502
503
504
505
506
507
508
509
510
511
512
513
514
515
516
517
518
519
520
521
522
523
524
525
526
527
528
529
530
531
532
533
534
535
536
537
538
539
540
541
542
543
544
545
546
547
548
549
550
551
552
553
554
555
556
557
558
559
560
561
562
563
564
565
566
567
568
569
570
571
572
573
574
575
576
577
578
579
580
581
582
583
584
585
586
587
588
589
590
591
592
593
594
595
596
597
598
599
600
601
602
603
604
605
606
607
608
609
610
611
612
613
614
615
616
617
618
619
620
621
622
623
624
625
626
627
628
629
630
631
632
633
634
635
636
637
638
639
640
641
642
643
644
645
646
647
648
649
650
651
652
653
654
655
656
657
658
659
660
661
662
663
664
665
666
667
668
669
670
671
672
673
674
675
676
677
678
679
680
681
682
683
684
685
686
687
688
689
690
691
692
693
694
695
696
697
698
699
700
701
702
703
704
705
706
707
708
709
710
711
712
713
714
715
716
717
718
719
720
721
722
723
724
725
726
727
728
729
730
731
732
733
734
735
736
737
738
739
740
741
742
743
744
745
746
747
748
749
750
751
752
753
754
755
756
757
758
759
760
761
762
763
764
765
766
767
768
769
770
771
772
773
774
775
776
777
778
779
780
781
782
783
784
785
786
787
788
789
790
791
792
793
794
795
796
797
798
799
800
801
802
803
804
805
806
807
808
809
810
811
812
813
814
815
816
817
818
819
820
821
822
823
824
825
826
827
828
829
830
831
832
833
834
835
836
837
838
839
840
841
842
843
844
845
846
847
848
849
850
851
852
853
854
855
856
857
858
859
860
861
862
863
864
865
866
867
868
869
870
871
872
873
874
875
876
877
878
879
880
881
882
883
884
885
886
887
888
889
890
891
892
893
894
895
896
897
898
899
900
901
902
903
904
905
906
907
908
909
910
911
912
913
914
915
916
917
918
919
920
921
922
923
924
925
926
927
928
929
930
931
932
933
934
935
936
937
938
939
940
941
942
943
944
945
946
947
948
949
950
951
952
953
954
955
956
957
958
959
960
961
962
963
964
965
966
967
968
969
970
971
972
973
974
975
976
977
978
979
980
981
982
983
984
985
986
987
988
989
990
991
992
993
994
995
996
997
998
999
1000
% -*- mode: LaTeX; TeX-PDF-mode: t; -*-
\input{@resources/tex-add-search-paths} % allow latex to find custom stuff
\input{./.econtexRoot}
\documentclass[BufferStockTheory]{subfiles}
\input{./.econtexRoot}
\usepackage{econark-ifsubfile}
\usepackage{econark-xrsetup}
\compilingasstandalone{
\xrsetup{\LaTeXGenerated/BufferStockTheory}
\providecommand{\texname}{}\renewcommand{\texname}{Introduction}
} % Get xrefs -- esp to apndx -- from main file; only works if main file has already been compiled
\begin{document}
\compilingasstandalone{standalone}
\compilingassubfile{subfile}
\hypertarget{The-Problem}{}
\section{Theoretical Foundations}\label{sec:Theory}
This section formalizes the consumer income fluctuation problem and proves the existence of a limiting non-degenerate solution. In doing so, we also introduce our consumer patience conditions and use them to derive the consumer's MPCs. The MPCs are formulae, for any period $t$ earlier than the terminal period $T$, for the maximum and minimum MPCs as wealth approaches zero and infinity. If the environment is that of an infinite-horizon `income fluctuation problem,' our formulae yield the limiting upper and lower bounds of the limiting non-degenerate solution.
We first state the finite horizon problem and then define the limiting solution as the limit of finite horizon solutions as the terminal period becomes arbitrarily distant. This way, the economic intuition of limiting consumer behaviour can be directly linked to consumer behaviour in life-cycle models (see \cite{gpLifeCycle} for an instance where buffer stock saving is discussed in the context of a life-cycle model). Nonetheless for the class of problems we consider, a non-degenerate limiting solution, if it exists, is mathematically equivalent (\cite{bertsekas2012dynamic}, Ch. 1.) to a stationary solution to an infinite stochastic sequence problem commonly used in the literature (for example, \cite{mstIncFluct}).
\label{sec:Foundations}
\subsection{Setup}\label{subsec:Setup}
We start by stating the consumer problem with permanent income growth in levels and then normalize by permanent income. The normalized problem then becomes the subject of our formal results in the paper.
Our time index $t$ can take on values in $\{T,T-1,T-2,\dots \}$. We assume that our consumer has a Constant Relative Risk Aversion (CRRA) per-period utility function, $\uFunc(c)=\frac{c^{1-\CRRA}}{1-\CRRA}$, where $\CRRA>1$. The term $\DiscFac$ is the (strictly positive) discount factor. In each period $t$, the consumer faces independently and identically distributed (iid) income shocks, with the permanent shock given by $\permShk_{t} \in \Reals_{++}$ and the transitory shock by $\tranShkAll_{t} \in \Reals_{+}$.\footnote{Formally, we assume $\left\{\permShk_{t},\tranShkAll_{t}\right\}_{t=-\infty}^{T}$ is a sequence of iid random variables defined on a common probability space $(\Omega, \Sigma, \mathbb{P})$. When used without the time subscript, $\permShk$ and $\tranShkAll$ are the canonical random variables with distributions $\mathbb{P}\circ \permShk_{0}^{-1}$ and $\mathbb{P}\circ \tranShkAll_{0}^{-1}$, respectively.}
In each $t$, the finite horizon value function for the problem in levels will be denoted by $\vFuncLvl_{t}$, with $\vFuncLvl_{t}\colon \Reals_{++}^{2}\rightarrow \Reals$. Value, $\vFunc_{t}(\mLvl_{t}, \permLvl_{t})$, depends on two strictly positive state variables: `market resources' $\mLvl_{t}$ and permanent income $\permLvl_{t}$.
After the terminal period, we assume the consumer cannot die in debt:
%
\begin{equation}\label{eq:NoDebtAtDeath}
\cLvl_{T} \leq \mLvl_{T} .
\end{equation}
%
Letting $\vFuncLvl_{T+1} = 0$, it follows that the value function for the terminal period satisfies $\vFuncLvl_{T} = \uFunc(\mNrm_{T})$.
For $t<T$, the finite-horizon value functions are recursively defined by:
%
\begin{verbatimwrite}{Equations/supfn}
\begin{align}\label{eq:levelRecProblem}
\vFuncLvl_{t}(\mLvl_{t}, \permLvl_{t})\colon & = \max_{0 < \cLvl_{t} \leq \mLvl_{t}} \uFunc(\cLvl_{t}) + \DiscFac \Ex_{t}\vFuncLvl_{t+1}(\mLvl_{t+1}, \permLvl_{t+1}), \qquad (\mLvl_{t}, \permLvl_{t})\in \Reals_{++}^{2} \tag{$\mathscr{P}_{L}$}
\end{align}
\end{verbatimwrite}
\input{Equations/supfn}
where i) $\cLvl_{t}$ is the level of consumption at time $t$, ii) $\Ex_{t}$ is the expectation operator over the shocks $\permShk_{t+1}$ and $\tranShkAll_{t+1}$\hypertarget{checkRestrictions}{}\hypertarget{DBCparts}{}, and iii) $\mLvl_{t+1}$ is determined from this period's $\mLvl_{t}$ and choice of $\cLvl_{t}$ as follows:\footnote{For maximal clarity, we have separately described every step in the dynamic budget evolution.
The steps are broken down also so that the notation of the paper will correspond exactly to the variable names in the \href{https://github.com/econ-ark/HARK} toolkit, because it is required for solving life cycle problems.}%$^{,}$\footnote{Allowing a stochastic interest factor would complicate the notation but not affect the points we want to address; however, see~\cite{benhabibWealth},~\cite{maTodaRich}, and~\cite{mstIncFluct} for the implications of capital income risk for the distribution of wealth and other interesting questions not considered here.}
%
\begin{verbatimwrite}{Equations/DBCparts}
\begin{equation}\label{eq:DBCparts} % Don't define it if already defined
\begin{split}
\aLvl_{t} & = \mLvl_{t}-\cLvl_{t} \\
\kLvl_{t+1} & = \aLvl_{t} \notag \\
\permLvl_{t+1} & = \permLvl_{t} \underbrace{\PermGroFac\permShk_{t+1}}_{:= \Rnd{\PermGroFac}_{t+1}} \notag \\
\mLvl_{t+1} & = \underbrace{\Rfree \kLvl_{t+1}}_{:= \bLvl_{t+1}} +\underbrace{\permLvl_{t+1}\tranShkAll_{t+1}}_{:= \yLvl_{t+1}}. \notag
\end{split}
\end{equation}
\end{verbatimwrite}
\input{Equations/DBCParts}
%
The consumer's assets at the end of $t$, $\aLvl_{t}$, translate one-for-one into capital $\kLvl_{t+1}$ at the beginning of the next period.
In turn, $\kLvl_{t+1}$ is augmented by a fixed interest factor $\Rfree$ to become the consumer's financial (`bank') balances $\bLvl_{t+1} = \Rfree \kLvl_{t+1}$.`Market resources,' $\mLvl_{t+1}$, are the sum of financial wealth $\Rfree \kLvl_{t+1}$ and noncapital income $\yLvl_{t+1}=\permLvl_{t+1}\tranShkAll_{t+1}$ (permanent noncapital income $\permLvl_{t+1}$ multiplied by the transitory shock $\tranShkAll_{t+1}$).
Permanent noncapital income $\permLvl_{t+1}$ is derived from $\permLvl_{t}$ by application of a growth factor $\PermGroFac$,\footnote{A time-varying $\PermGroFac$ has straightforward consequences for the analysis below; this is an option allowed for in the \href{https://econ-ark.org}{HARK} toolkit.} modified by the permanent income shock $\permShk_{t+1}$, and the resulting idiosyncratic growth factor for permanent income is written as $\Rnd{\PermGroFac}_{t+1}$.
Letting $n$ denote the planning horizon, the finite-horizon problems furnish a sequence of value functions $\{\vFuncLvl_{T},\vFuncLvl_{T-1},\ldots,\vFuncLvl_{T-n}\}$ and associated consumption functions $\{\cFuncLvl_{T},\cFuncLvl_{T-1},\ldots,\cFuncLvl_{T-n}\}$.
The limiting consumption function, denoted by $\usual{\cFuncLvl}(\mLvl,\permLvl) = \lim\limits_{n \rightarrow \infty} \cFuncLvl_{T-n}(\mLvl,\permLvl)$, will be called a `non-degenerate limiting solution' if neither $\usual{\cFuncLvl}=0$ everywhere (for all $(\mLvl,\permLvl)$) nor $\usual{\cFuncLvl}=\infty$ everywhere.
Before turning to the normalized problem, we present the income process and its implications for the consumer problem.
The following assumption defines the income process.
\begin{assumI}\label{ass:shocks}(Friedman-Muth Income Process).
For each $t$:
\begin{enumerate}
\item The permanent shock, $\permShk_{t}$, satisfies $\Ex[{\permShk}_{t}]=1$ and $\permShk_{t}\in [\permShkIndMin,\permShkIndMax]$ s.t. $0 < \permShkIndMin \leq 1$ and $1 \leq \permShkIndMax < \infty$.
\item The transitory shock, $\tranShkAll_{t}$, satisfies:
\begin{verbatimwrite}{Equations/TranShkDef}
\begin{equation}
\tranShkAll_{t}=
\begin{cases}
0\phantom{_{t+1}/\pNotZero} & \text{with probability $\pZero > 0$} \\
\tranShkEmp_{t}/\pNotZero & \text{with probability $\pNotZero $}, % \equiv 1-\pZero
\end{cases} \label{eq:TranShkDef}
\end{equation}
\end{verbatimwrite}
\input{Equations/TranShkDef}
\noindent for iid random variable $\tranShkEmp_{t}$, with $\Ex[{\tranShkEmp}_{t}]=1$ and $ \tranShkEmp_{t} \in [\Min{\tranShkEmp}, \bar{\tranShkEmp}]$ s.t.
$\tranShkEmpMin >0$ and $\Min{\tranShkEmp} \leq 1 \leq \Max{\tranShkEmp} < \infty$.
\end{enumerate}
\end{assumI}
Following~\cite{zeldesStochastic}, the income process incorporates a small probability $\pZero$ that income will be zero (a `zero-income event').
At date $T-1$, the (strictly positive) probability $q$ of zero income in period $T$ will prevent the consumer from spending all resources, because saving nothing would mean arriving in the following period with zero bank balances and thus facing the possibility of being required to consume 0, which would yield utility of $-\infty$.
This logic holds recursively from $T-1$ back, so the consumer will never spend everything, giving rise to what \cite{aiyagari:ge} dubbed a `natural borrowing constraint.'\footnote{We specify zero as the lowest-possible-income event without loss of generality \citep{aiyagari:ge}.} (Thus, the upper-bound constraint on consumption in the problem \eqref{eq:levelRecProblem} will not bind.)
\hypertarget{PDV}{}
The model looks more special than it is.
In particular, a positive probability of zero-income events may seem objectionable (despite empirical support).
However, a nonzero minimum value of $\tranShkAll$ (motivated, say, by the existence of unemployment insurance) could be handled by capitalizing the present discounted value (PDV) of minimum income into current market assets,\footnote{So long as unemployment benefits are proportional to $\permLvl_{t}$; see the discussion in Section~\ref{subsubsec:ratio}.} and transforming that model back into this one.
And no key results would change if the transitory shocks were persistent but mean-reverting (instead of iid).\@ Also, the assumption of a positive point mass for the worst realization of the transitory shock is inessential, but simplifies the proofs and is a powerful aid to intuition.
\begin{comment}
Following footnotes and text were removed from the discussion above
\footnote{\cite{rabaultBorrowing} and~\cite{lsIncFluct} analyze cases where the shock processes have unbounded support.}
and when $\permShkIndMin=\permShkIndMax=1$ the model becomes the degenerate case with no permanent shocks
\end{comment}
\hypertarget{The-Problem-Can-Be-Rewritten-in-Ratio-Form}{}
\hypertarget{The-Problem-Can-Be-Normalized-By-Permanent-Income}{}
\subsubsection{Normalized Problem}\label{subsubsec:ratio}
Let nonbold variables be the boldface counterpart normalized by $\permLvl_{t}$, allowing us to reduce the number of states from two ($\mLvl$ and $\permLvl$) to one $(\mNrm = \mLvl/\permLvl)$.
Now, in a one-time deviation from the notational convention established in the last sentence, define nonbold `normalized value' not as $\vLvl_{t}/\permLvl_{t}$ but as $\vNrm_{t} = \vLvl_{t}/\permLvl_{t}^{1-\CRRA}$, because this allows us to write nonbold $\vFunc_{t}$, with $\vFunc_{t}\colon \Reals_{++}\rightarrow \Reals$, to denote the `normalized value function':
%
%
\begin{equation}\label{eq:veqnNrmRecBellman}
\begin{split}
% \begin{align*}
\vFunc_{t}(\mNrm_{t}) & = \max_{0<\cNrm_{t}< \mNrm_{t}}~ \uFunc(\cNrm_{t}) +\DiscFac \Ex_{t}[\Rnd{\PermGroFac}_{t+1}^{1-\CRRA}\vFunc_{t+1}({\mNrm}_{t+1})],\qquad \mNrm_{t}\in \Reals_{++}\\
& \mbox{s.t.}
\\ {\aNrm}_{t} & = \mNrm_{t}-c_{t}
\\ {\kNrm}_{t+1} & = \aNrm_{t}/\Rnd{\PermGroFac}_{t+1} = \RNrmByGRnd_{t+1}\aNrm_{t}
\\ {\bNrm}_{t+1} & = \kNrm_{t+1} \Rfree %\Rnd{\PermGroFac}_{t+1} %= ~ \RNrmByGRnd_{t+1}\aNrm_{t} = \RNrmByGRnd_{t+1}\aNrm_{t}
\\ \mNrm_{t+1} & = \bNrm_{t+1} +\tranShkAll_{t+1} ,
% \end{align*}
\end{split} \tag{$\mathscr{P}_{N}$}
\end{equation}
where $\RNrmByGRnd_{t+1}\colon = (\Rfree/\PermGroFacRnd_{t+1})$ is a `permanent-income-growth-normalized' return factor.
(Appendix \ref{sec:recoverLevels} explains how the solution to the original problem in levels can be recovered from the normalized problem.)
The time $t$ normalized consumption \textit{policy function} for the finite-horizon problem, $\cFunc_{t}$, is defined by:
%
\begin{equation}\label{eq:cfunceq1}
\cFunc_{t}(\mNrm_{t})\colon = \argmax_{0<\cNrm_{t}< \mNrm_{t}}~ \uFunc(\cNrm_{t}) +\DiscFac \Ex_{t}[\Rnd{\PermGroFac}_{t+1}^{1-\CRRA}\vFunc_{t+1}(\mNrm_{t+1} )].
\end{equation}
%
The normalized problem's first order condition becomes:
\begin{align}
c_{t}^{-\CRRA} & = \Rfree \DiscFac \Ex_{t}[ \Rnd{\PermGroFac}_{t+1}^{-\CRRA} \cNrm_{t+1}^{-\CRRA}]. \label{eq:scaledeuler}
\end{align}
\hypertarget{sensible}{}\hypertarget{useful}{}
\hypertarget{Definition-of-a-Nondegenerate-Solution and Bellman}{}
Since our main results pertain to the normalized problem, we define the limiting non-degenerate solution to the normalized problem formally.
\begin{definition}\label{def:nondegeneracy}(Non-degenerate Limiting Solution)
\ref{eq:veqnNrmRecBellman} has a non-degenerate limiting solution if there exists $ \usual{\cFunc}$, with $\usual{\cFunc}\colon \Reals_{++}\rightarrow \Reals_{++}$, and $ \usual{\vFunc}$, with $\usual{\vFunc}\colon \Reals_{++}\rightarrow \Reals$, such that:
%
\begin{align*}
\usual{\cFunc}(\mNrm) = \lim_{n \rightarrow \infty} \cFunc_{T-n}(\mNrm), \quad \usual{\vFunc}(\mNrm) = \lim_{n \rightarrow \infty} \vFunc_{T-n}(\mNrm), \qquad \mNrm \in \Reals_{++} \notag.
\end{align*}
\end{definition}
\hypertarget{Stationary-Bellman-Operator}{}
We use $\TMap$ to denote the stationary Bellman operator for the normalized problem.
To define $\TMap$, let $\RNrmByGRnd \colon = \Rfree/\PermGroFacRnd$ and let $\TMap$ denote the mapping $\vFunc_{t+1} \mapsto \vFunc_{t}$ given by Problem \ref{eq:veqnNrmRecBellman}:
%
\begin{equation}\label{eq:maintmap}
\TMap \vFunc_{t+1}(\mNrm) = \max_{\cNrm \in (0, \mNrm) } \left\{
\uFunc(c) + \DiscFac\Ex\Rnd{\PermGroFac}^{1-\CRRA}\vFunc_{t+1}(\RNrmByGRnd(m - c) + \tranShkAll)
\right\}, \quad m \in \Reals_{++}.
\end{equation}
%
The mapping $\mNrm\mapsto (0, \mNrm)$ defines the feasibility correspondence.
To define $\TMap$, we excluded the boundary of the feasible values that consumption can take ($0$ and $\mNrm$) to ensure the maximand above is real-valued for all feasible values of consumption.
It is straightforward to show (using the Bellman Principle of Optimality) that a finite valued solution, $\vFunc$, to the functional equation $\TMap\vFunc = \vFunc$ defines a \hyperlink{sensible}{limiting non-degenerate solution}.
However, because the feasibility correspondence does not include the boundary of feasible consumption, existing dynamic programming arguments cannot be used to show that such a solution (a fixed point to $\TMap$) exists.
\subsubsection{Dynamic Programming Challenges}\label{subsubsec:challengesDP} \hypertarget{challengesDP}{} Standard dynamic programming \citep{stachurski2022} works by showing that $\TMap$ is a well-defined contraction map on a Banach space, which would allow us to conclude that the sequence of value functions given by Problem \ref{eq:veqnNrmRecBellman} converges to a fixed point of $\TMap$, a non-degenerate solution.
At first, we must contend with the fact that both $\uFunc$ and $\vFunc$ are unbounded below.
We resolve unboundedness by constructing a weighted-norm (see below).
Setting aside unboundedness, the natural liquidity constraint introduces a more pernicious challenge related to continuity: $\TMap$ will not a be well defined self-map on a vector space of continuous functions.
In particular, we cannot assert $\TMap$ maps continuous functions to continuous functions since the feasiblility correspondence $\mNrm\mapsto (0, \mNrm)$ is not compact-valued.
\begin{remark}\label{remark:notCompact}
Since the correspondence $\mNrm\mapsto (0, \mNrm)$ is not compact valued, the conditions of Berge's Maximum Theorem (Lemma 1, \cite{Jaskiewicz2011}) fail and $\TMap \fFunc$ may not be continuous for continuous $\fFunc$.
\end{remark}
If we reintroduce the boundary points $0$ and $\mNrm$ to the feasibility correspondence, the operator $\TMap$ will be able to map upper semicontinuous functions to upper semicontinuous functions (Lemma 1, \cite{Jaskiewicz2011}).
However, $\vFunc$ must now be defined on $\Reals_{+}$ and take on values in $\mathbb{R}_{+}\cup\{-\infty\}$ and spaces of such functions will not be a vector space.
The approach taken by \cite{Ma2022} is to impose an artificial liquidity constraint, which yields a real-valued continuation value, even if $\cNrm= \mNrm$, and forces the value function to be bounded below as a function of end-of-period assets.
This allows \cite{Ma2022} to define a functional operator operator within which the feasibiltiy correspondence is the compact interval $[0, \mNrm]$.
Without an artificial constraint, no such strategy is possible.\footnote{The challenge of continuity and compactness remains unresolved in a general setting \citep{rinconZapatero2024}.
Relevant results include \cite{Feinberg2012}, who generalize the requirement of continuity of feasibility correspondences to K-Inf-Compactness of the Bellman operator, yielding a mapping from semi-continuous to semi-continuous functions.
\cite{Shanker2017a} introduces a generalization, mild-Sup-compactness, which can be verified in the weak topology generated on the infinite dimensional product space of feasible random variables controlled by the consumers.
Our approach, by contrast, has the advantage that it can be used to verify existence using more standard tools.}
A related approach, which uses Euler operators is used by \cite{mstIncFluct}.
While \cite{mstIncFluct} also assume an artificial liquidity constraint to bound the marginal utility of consumption, it is useful to consider how the structure of our model relates to theirs once the artificial liquidity constraint is imposed.
\begin{remark}\label{remark:stochdiscMST}
If $\pZero=0$, \eqref{eq:veqnNrmRecBellman} becomes a special case of \cite{mstIncFluct}, with $\RNrmByGRnd_{t+1}=\Rfree/\Rnd{\PermGroFac}_{t+1}$ corresponding to the stochastic rate of return on capital and $\DiscFac \Rnd{\PermGroFac}_{t+1}^{1-\CRRA}$ corresponding to the stochastic discount factor.
\end{remark}
Notwithstanding Remark \ref{remark:stochdiscMST}, there are important economic consequences relating consumer patience to buffer stock saving due to the fact that in our problem $\RNrmByGRnd_{t+1}=\Rfree/\Rnd{\PermGroFac}_{t+1}$ is tightly tied to the `normalized stochastic discount factor,' $\DiscFac \Rnd{\PermGroFac}_{t+1}^{1-\CRRA}$; these will become apparent as we proceed.
\hypertarget{GICTheorySetup}{}
\subsection{Consumer Patience Conditions}\label{subsec:GICTheorySetup}
In order to have a central reference point for them, we now collect conditions relating consumer discounting and patience to the rate of return and income growth that underpin results in the remainder of the paper.
Assumptions \ref{ass:FVAC} - \ref{ass:RIC} (finite value of autarky, return impatience and weak return impatience) will be used to prove the existence of limiting solutions in Section \ref{subsec:limSolExists}, and Assumptions \ref{ass:GICRaw} - \ref{ass:GICMod} (growth impatience and strong growth impatience) are required for existence of alternative definitions of a stable target buffer stock in Section \ref{sec:individStability}.
We start by generalizing the standard $\DiscFac<1$ condition to our setting with permanent income growth and uncertainty.\footnote{In light of Remark \ref{remark:stochdiscMST}, \cite{mstIncFluct} Assumption 2.1 is a generalization of this discount condition, albeit in a context with artificial liquidity constraints.} The updated condition requires that the expected net discounted value of utility from consumption is finite under our definition of `autarky' -- where consumption is always equal to permanent income.
A finite value of autarky helps guarantee that as the horizon extends, discounted value remains finite along \textit{any} consumption path the consumer might choose.
(See Appendix~\ref{sec:ApndxConcaveCFunc}).
\hypertarget{FVAC}{}
\begin{assumL}\label{ass:FVAC}(Finite Value of Autarky).
%
$0 < \DiscFac \PermGroFac^{1-\CRRA}\Ex(\permShk^{1-\CRRA}) < 1 $.
%
\end{assumL}
We now turn to consumer patience and start with `absolute (im)patience.'
We will say that an unconstrained perfect foresight consumer exhibits absolute impatience if they optimally choose to spend so much today that their consumption must decline in the future.
The growth factor for consumption implied by the Euler equation of a perfect foresight model is $\cLvl_{t+1}/\cLvl_{t} = {(\Rfree\DiscFac)}^{1/\CRRA}$,\footnote{See \eqref{eq:cGroFac} below.} which motivates our definition of an `absolute patience factor' whose centrality (to everything that is to come later) justifies assigning to it a special symbol; we have settled on the archaic letter \href{https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Thorn_(letter)}{`thorn'}:
\hypertarget{APFAC}{}
\begin{equation}\label{eq:APFac}
\APFac \colon= {(\Rfree\DiscFac)}^{1/\CRRA}.
\end{equation}
We will say that (in the perfect foresight problem) `an absolutely impatient' consumer is one for whom $\APFac < 1$; that is an absolutely impatient consumer prefers to consume more today than tomorrow (and vice versa for an `absolutely patient' consumer, whose consumption will grow over time):
\hypertarget{AIC}{}
\begin{assumL} (\textit{Absolute Impatience}). \label{ass:AIC}
$\APFac < 1$.
\end{assumL}
A consumer who is absolutely impatient, $\APFac<1$, satisfies the standard impatience condition commonly used in the income fluctuation literature, $\DiscFac\Rfree<1$, which guarantees the existence of a stable asset distribution when there is no permanent income growth.
However, as pointed out by \cite{szeidlInvariant} and \cite{maUnboundedDP}, $\DiscFac\Rfree<1$ is not necessary for an infinite-horizon solution.
Recall now our earlier requirement that the limiting consumption function $\cFunc(\mNrm)$ in our model must be `sensible.'
We will show below that for the perfect foresight unconstrained problem this requires
\hypertarget{RIC}{}
\begin{assumL} (\textit{Return Impatience}).\label{ass:RIC}
$\RPFac < 1$.
\end{assumL}
Return impatience can be best understood as the tension between the income effect of capital income and the substitution effect.
As we show below in Section \ref{subsec:PFBbenchmark}, in the perfect foresight model, it is straightforward to derive the MPC out of overall (human plus nonhuman) wealth that would result in next period's wealth being identical to the current period's wealth.
The answer turns out to be an MPC (`$\MPC$') of $\MPC=(1-\APFac/\Rfree)$.
The interesting point here is that $\MPC$ depends both on our absolute patience factor $\APFac$ and on the return factor.
This is the manifestation in this context of the interaction of the income effect (higher wealth yields higher interest income if $\Rfree>1$) and the substitution effect (which we have already captured with $\APFac$).
Next, consider the weaker condition of a consumer whose \hyperlink{APFAC}{absolute patience factor} is suitably adjusted to take account of the probability of zero income is less than the market return.
%
\hypertarget{WRIC}{}
\begin{assumL} (\textit{Weak Return Impatience}). \label{ass:WRIC}
$\underbrace{\frac{(\pZero \Rfree \DiscFac)^{1/\CRRA}}{\Rfree}}_{ = \frac{\pZero^{1/\CRRA} \APFac}{\Rfree}} < 1. \phantom{\text{{\WRIC}:~~}}$
%
\end{assumL}
This condition is `weak' (relative to the plain return impatience) because the probability of the zero income events $\pZero$ is strictly less than 1.
The role of $\pZero$ in this equation is related to the fact that a consumer with zero end-of-period assets today has a probability $\pZero$ of having no income and no assets to finance consumption (and $\mNrm_{t+1}=0$ would yield negative infinite utility).
In the case with no artificial constraint, our main results below, in Section \ref{subsec:limSolExists}, show weak return impatience and finite value of autarky are sufficient to guarantee a sensible (non-degenerate) solution.
Weak return impatience cannot be relaxed further without an artificial liquidity constraint.
Even though $\pZero^{1/\CRRA} \RPFac\rightarrow 0$ as $\pZero\rightarrow 0$ the weak return impatience condition \textit{does not} approach irrelevance as the possibility of the zero income event approaches zero.
Instead, we show below in Section \ref{subsubsec:deatonIsLimit} that the limiting consumption function with a natural constraint approaches the solution to a model with an artificial constraint.
%
Now that we have finished discussing the requirements for a non-degenerate solution, we turn to assumptions required for stability.
We speak of a consumer whose \hyperlink{APFAC}{absolute patience factor} is less than the expected growth factor for their permanent income $\PermGroFac = \Ex[\PermGroFac \permShk])$ as exhibiting `growth impatience:'
\hypertarget{GPFacRawDefn}{}
\hypertarget{GICRaw}{}
\begin{assumS}\label{ass:GICRaw} (\textit{Growth Impatience}).
$ \GPFacRaw < 1$.
\end{assumS}
\begin{comment}
\begin{verbatimwrite}{Equations/GICRaw}
\begin{equation}\begin{gathered}\begin{aligned}
\text{\GICRaw:~~} && \GPFacRaw < 1 . \phantom{/\PermGroFac}& \phantom{\text{\GICRaw:~~}} \label{eq:GICRaw}
\end{aligned}\end{gathered}\end{equation}
\end{verbatimwrite}
\input{Equations/GICRaw}
\end{assumS}
\end{comment}
A final useful definition is `strong growth impatience' which holds for a consumer for whom the expectation of the \textit{ratio} of the \hyperlink{APFAC}{absolute patience factor} to the growth factor of permanent income is less than one,
\hypertarget{GICMod}{}
\begin{assumS}(\textit{Strong Growth Impatience}). \label{ass:GICMod}
$ \Ex\left[\frac{\APFac}{\PermGroFac \permShk}\right] = \GPFacMod < 1.$
\end{assumS}
(The difference between growth impatience and strong growth impatience is that the first is the ratio of an expectation to an expectation, while the latter is the expectation of the ratio.
With non-degenerate mean-one stochastic shocks to permanent income, the expectation of the ratio is strictly larger than the ratio of the expectations).
\begin{comment}
\begin{verbatimwrite}{Equations/GICMod}
\begin{align}
\text{{\GICMod}:~~} \GPFacMod & < 1 . \phantom{\text{{\GICMod}:~~}}\label{eq:GICMod}
\end{align}\end{verbatimwrite}
\input{Equations/GICMod}
\end{comment}
%$ AS TO CDC can we remove the comment below? No need to state the results in this Section before they are presented.
\begin{comment}
below stuff goes in growth section.
Strong growth impatience guarantees that the \textit{expectation} of normalized market resources becomes less than one market resources limit to infinity, since the condition will imply $\min \{\Ex\frac{\APFac}{\Rnd{\PermGroFac}}, \Ex\frac{R}{\Rnd{\PermGroFac}}\}< \GPFacMod<1$.
The growth impatience condition relates the \textit{expected} growth factor of permanent income to the \hyperlink{APFAC}{absolute patience factor}.
Following the discussion below Assumption \ref{ass:RIC}, the growth factor of the ratio of expected market resources to expected permanent income as $m$ limits to infinity becomes $\min \{\frac{\APFac}{\PermGroFac}, \frac{R}{\PermGroFac}\}$, and we have $\min \{\frac{\APFac}{\PermGroFac}, \frac{R}{\PermGroFac}\}< \GPFacRaw$.
Thus, growth impatience ensures the ratio of \textit{expected} market resources to \textit{expected} permanent income eventually falls as $\mNrm$ grows.
\end{comment}
While neither growth impatience nor return impatience will by themselves be required for the existence of a limiting solution, the finite value of autarky condition stops individuals from becoming \textit{both} growth and return patient.
\begin{claim}\label{claim:noRICGIC}
If \hyperlink{GIC}{growth impatience} fails ($\GPFacRaw \geq 1$) and \hyperlink{RIC}{return impatience} fails ($\RPFac \geq 1$), then \hyperlink{FVAC}{finite value of autarky} fails ($\DiscFac \PermGroFac^{1-\CRRA}\Ex(\permShk^{1-\CRRA})\geq 1$).
\end{claim}
\begin{proof}
Since $\RPFac > 1$, $\RPFac $ satisfies:
%
%
\begin{equation}
\RPFac = \frac{\left(\Rfree\DiscFac\right)^{\frac{1}{\CRRA}}}{\Rfree}\geq 1.
\end{equation}
%
Multiplying both sides by $\Rfree\PermGroFac^{1-\CRRA}$ gives us:
%
\begin{equation}
\DiscFac\PermGroFac^{1-\CRRA}\Rfree^{\frac{1}{\CRRA}}\DiscFac^{\frac{1-\CRRA}{\CRRA}}{}\geq\Rfree \PermGroFac^{1-\CRRA} \Rightarrow \DiscFac\PermGroFac^{1-\CRRA}\geq\left(\frac{\APFac}{\PermGroFac}\right)^{\CRRA-1}.
\end{equation}
%
Finally, since $\CRRA>1$, applying $\GPFacRaw \geq 1$ gives us the result.
\end{proof}
We discuss further intuition for the consumer patience conditions below when they are used in the main results.
The relationship between the conditions and their implications for consumption behaviour will also be be discussed in detail in Section \ref{sec:GICdiscussion}.
\hypertarget{Perfect-Foresight-Benchmarks}{}
\subsection{Perfect Foresight Benchmarks}\label{subsec:PFBbenchmark}
To understand the economic implications of the patience conditions, we begin with the perfect foresight case.
Below, when we say we assume perfect foresight, what we mean mathematically is:
%
\begin{assumI}\label{ass:pfincome}(Perfect Foresight Income Process).
$\pZero=0$ and $\tranShkEmpMin=\tranShkEmpMax=\bar{\tranShkEmp}=\permShkIndMin=\permShkIndMax=1$
\end{assumI}
Throughout this sub-section, we assume Assumption \ref{ass:pfincome} remains in force.
%
Under perfect foresight, \hyperlink{FVAC}{finite value of autarky} reduces to a `perfect foresight finite value of autarky' condition:
%
\hypertarget{PFFVAC}{}
\begin{equation}\begin{gathered}\begin{aligned}
\DiscFac \PermGroFac^{1-\CRRA} & < 1. \phantom{\text{\PFFVAC:~~}}
\end{aligned}\end{gathered}\label{eq:PFFVAC}\end{equation}
\subsubsection{Perfect Foresight without Liquidity Constraints}\label{subsubsec:PFUncon}
Consider the familiar analytical solution to the perfect foresight model without liquidity constraints.
In this case, the consumption Euler Equation always holds as an equality; with $\uP(\cLvl)=\cLvl^{-\CRRA}$ and $\uFunc^{\prime}(\cLvl_{t})=\Rfree\DiscFac\uFunc^{\prime}(\cLvl_{t+1})$, we have:
%
%
\begin{align}
\cLvl_{t+1}/\cLvl_{t} & = {(\Rfree\DiscFac)}^{1/\CRRA}. \label{eq:cGroFac}
\end{align}
%
Recalling $\RNrmByG = \Rfree/\PermGroFac$, `human wealth', is the present discounted value of income:
%
%
\begin{align}
\hLvl_{t} & = \permLvl_{t}+\RNrmByG^{-1} \permLvl_{t} + \RNrmByG^{-2} \permLvl_{t} + \cdots + \RNrmByG^{t-T} \permLvl_{t} \notag
\\ & = \underbrace{\left(\frac{1-\RNrmByG^{-(T-t+1)}}{1-\RNrmByG^{-1}}\right)}_{ = \colon \hNrm_{t}}\permLvl_{t} \label{eq:HDef}.
\end{align}
For human wealth to have finite value, we must have:
%
\begin{assumI}\label{ass:FHWC}(Finite Limiting Human Wealth).
\begin{align}\hypertarget{FHWC}{}
\RNrmByG^{-1} = \PermGroFac/\Rfree & < 1. \phantom{\text{{\FHWC}:~~}}\label{eq:FHWC2}
\end{align}
\end{assumI}
%
If $\RNrmByGRnd^{-1}$ is less than one, human wealth will be finite in the limit as $T \rightarrow \infty$ because (noncapital) income growth is smaller than the interest rate at which that income is being discounted.
Under these conditions we can define a normalized finite-horizon perfect foresight consumption function (see Appendix \ref{subsec:ApndxUCPF} for details) as follows:\hypertarget{MPCminDefn}{}
%
\begin{align*}
\bar{\cFunc}_{T-n}(\mNrm_{T-n}) & = (\overbrace{\mNrm_{T-n}-1}^{
= \colon \bNrm_{T-n}}+\hNrm_{T-n})\MPCmin_{t-n}
\end{align*}
%
where $\MPCmin_{t}$ is the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) and satisfies:
%
\begin{align}\label{eq:PFMPCminInv}
\MPCmin_{T-n}^{-1} = 1+\left(\MPSmax\right) \MPCmin_{T-n+1}^{-1}.
\end{align}
%
Let $\MPCmin = \lim\limits_{n\rightarrow\infty}\MPCmin_{T-n}$.
For $\Min{\MPC}$ to be strictly positive, we must impose \hyperlink{RIC}{return impatience}.
The limiting consumption function then becomes:
%
\begin{align}\label{eq:cFuncPFUnc}
\bar{\cFunc}(\mNrm) & = (\mNrm+\hNrm-1)\MPCmin,
\end{align}
%
where, under return impatience, the limiting MPC becomes:
%
%
\begin{equation}\label{eq:MPCminDef}
%\MPCmin \colon = \max\{0,1- \RPFac\}.
\MPCmin \colon = 1-\RPFac.
\end{equation}
%
%
%
In order to rule out the degenerate limiting solution in which $\bar{\cFunc}(\mNrm) = \infty$, we also require (in the limit as the horizon extends to infinity) that human wealth remain bounded (that is, we require \hyperlink{FHWC}{`finite limiting human wealth'}).
Thus, while \hyperlink{RIC}{return impatience} prevents a consumer from saving everything in the limit, \hyperlink{FHWC}{`finite limiting human wealth'} prevents infinite borrowing (against infinite human wealth) in the limit.
The following two results consider the normalized problem without liquidity constraints and with perfect foresight income (Assumption \ref{ass:pfincome}).
\begin{proposition}\label{prop:pfUCFHWC}
A non-degenerate limiting solution exists if and only if \hyperlink{FHWC}{finite limiting human wealth} ($\RNrmByG^{-1}<1$) and \hyperlink{RIC}{return impatience} (Assumption \ref{ass:RIC}) hold.
\end{proposition}
\begin{proof}\let\qed\relax
See Appendix \ref{subsec:ApndxUCPF} for the proof.
\end{proof}
\begin{claim}\label{claim:PFConspC}
Assume \hyperlink{FHWC}{finite limiting human wealth} ($\RNrmByG^{-1}<1$). If \hyperlink{GIC}{growth impatience} (Assumption \ref{ass:GICRaw}) holds, then \hyperlink{FVAC}{finite value of autarky} (Assumption \ref{ass:FVAC}) holds. If \hyperlink{FVAC}{finite value of autarky} (Assumption \ref{ass:FVAC}) holds, then \hyperlink{RIC}{return impatience} (Assumption \ref{ass:RIC}) holds.
\end{claim}
\begin{proof}\let\qed\relax
See Appendix \ref{subsec:PFBProofs} for the proof.
\end{proof}
The claim implies that if we impose \hyperlink{FHWC}{finite limiting human wealth}, then \hyperlink{GIC}{growth impatience} is sufficient for nondegeneracy since \hyperlink{FVAC}{finite value of autarky} and \hyperlink{RIC}{return impatience} follow.
However, there are circumstances under which \hyperlink{RIC}{return impatience} and \hyperlink{FHWC}{finite limiting human wealth} can hold while the \hyperlink{FVAC}{finite value of autarky} fails.
For example, if $\PermGroFac=0$, the problem is a standard `cake-eating' problem with a non-degenerate solution under \hyperlink{RIC}{return impatience}.
\subsubsection{Perfect Foresight with Liquidity Constraints}
Our ultimate interest is in the unconstrained problem with uncertainty.
Here, we show that the perfect foresight constrained solution defines a useful limit for the unconstrained problem with uncertainty.
Consider that if a liquidity constraint requiring $\aNrm_{t} \geq 0$ binds at any $\mNrm_{t}$, it must bind at the lowest possible level of $\mNrm_{t}$, $\mNrm_{t}=1$, defined by the lower bound of having arrived into the period with $\bNrm_{t}=0$ (if the constraint were binding at any higher $\mNrm_{t}$, it would certainly be binding here, because $\uFunc^{\prime\prime}<0$ and $\cFunc^{\prime}>0$).
At $\mNrm_{t}=1$ the constraint binds if the marginal utility from spending all of today's resources $c_{t}=m_{t}=1$, exceeds the marginal utility from doing the same thing next period, $\cNrm_{t+1}=1$; that is, if such choices would violate the Euler equation, Equation ~\eqref{eq:scaledeuler}, yielding
\begin{align}
1^{-\CRRA} & > \Rfree \DiscFac \PermGroFac^{-\CRRA}1^{-\CRRA}, \label{eq:LiqConstrBinds}
\end{align}
which is just a restatement of \hyperlink{GIC}{growth impatience}.
So, the constraint is relevant if and only if \hyperlink{GICRaw}{growth impatience} holds.
For the following result, consider the normalized perfect foresight problem with a liquidity constraint (that is, assume $\cNrm_{t}\leq \mNrm_{t}$ for each $t$.)
\begin{proposition}\label{prop:PFCExist}
If \hyperlink{RIC}{return impatience} (Assumption \ref{ass:RIC}) holds, then a non-degenerate solution exists. Moreover, if \hyperlink{RIC}{return impatience} does not hold, then a non-degenerate solution exists if and only if \hyperlink{GICRaw}{growth impatience} (Assumption \ref{ass:GICRaw}) holds.
\end{proposition}
The proof for the result follows from the discussion in Section \ref{subsec:PFCon}, which outlines the cases under which perfect foresight liquidity constraint solutions are non-degenerate.
Importantly, if \hyperlink{RIC}{return impatience} fails ($\Rfree\leq \APFac$) and \hyperlink{GIC}{growth impatience} holds ($\APFac<\PermGroFac$), then \hyperlink{FHWC}{finite limiting human wealth} also fails $(\Rfree \leq \PermGroFac)$.
Despite the unboundedness of human wealth as the horizon extends arbitrarily, for any finite horizon the relevant liquidity constraint prevents borrowing.
Similarly, when uncertainty is present, the natural borrowing constraint plays an analogous role in permitting a finite limiting solution with unbounded limiting human wealth -- we discuss the various parametric cases in Section \ref{sec:GICdiscussion}.
\hypertarget{limsolexists}{}
\subsection{Main Results for Problem with Uncertainty}\label{subsec:limSolExists}
We are now ready to return to our primary interest, the model with permanent and transitory income shocks.
Throughout this section, we assume the Friedman-Muth income process (Assumption \ref{ass:shocks} holds) and examine the normalized problem, Problem \ref{eq:veqnNrmRecBellman}.
\subsubsection{Limiting MPCs}\label{subsubsec:cFuncBounds}
We first establish results regarding the shape of the consumption function.\footnote{\cite{ckConcavity} proved concavity but not continuous differentiability.}
\begin{proposition} \label{prop:cfuncprop} For each $t$, $\cFunc_{t}$ is twice continuously differentiable, increasing and strictly concave.
\end{proposition}
\begin{proof}\let\qed\relax
See Appendix~\ref{sec:MPCiterproofs} for the proof.
\end{proof}
Next, we note that the ratio of optimal consumption to market resources ($\cNrm/\mNrm$) is bounded by the minimal and maximal marginal propensities to consume (MPCs).
Recall that the MPCs answer the question `if the consumer had an extra unit of resources, how much more spending would occur?', The minimal and maximal MPCs are the limits of the MPC as $\mNrm \rightarrow \infty$ and $\mNrm \rightarrow 0$, which we denote by $\MPCmin_{t}$ and $\MPCmax_{t}$ respectively.
Since the consumer spends everything in the terminal period, $\MPCmin_{T}=1$ and $\MPCmax_{T}=1$.
Furthermore, Proposition \ref{prop:cfuncprop} will imply:\footnote{Note $\usual{\cFunc}_{t}^{\prime}$ is positive, bounded above by 1 and decreasing, then apply L'H\^{o}pital's Rule.}
%
\begin{align}\label{eq:cBounds}
\MPCmin_{t} \mNrm_{t} ~ \leq & ~ \usual{\cFunc}_{t}(\mNrm_{t}) \leq ~ \MPCmax_{t} \mNrm_{t} .
\end{align}
We define:
%
\hypertarget{MPCmaxDefn}{}\hypertarget{MPCminDefn}{}
\begin{equation}
\MPCmin \colon = \max\{0,1- \RPFac\}, \label{eq:MPCminDefn}
\end{equation}
\begin{equation}
\MPCmax \colon = 1 - \pZero^{1/\gamma}\RPFac, \label{eq:MPCmaxDefn}
\end{equation}
as the `limiting minimal and maximal MPCs'.
The following result verifies that the consumption share is bounded each period by the minimal and maximal MPCs, that the consumption function is asymptotically linear and that the MPCs converge to the limiting MPCs as the terminal period recedes.\footnote{\cite{benhabibWealth} show that the consumption function becomes linear as wealth approaches infinity in a model with capital income risk and liquidity constraints;~\cite{maTodaRich} show that these results generalize to the limits derived here if capital income is added to the model.}
\hypertarget{cFuncBounds}{}
\begin{lemma}(Limiting MPCs).
\label{lemm:MPC}
If \hyperlink{WRIC}{weak return impatience} (Assumption \ref{ass:WRIC}) holds, then:
\begin{enumerate}[label=(\roman*)]
\item For each $n$:
%
\begin{equation}\label{eq:MPCminInv}
\MPCmin_{T-n}^{-1} = 1+\left(\MPSmax\right) \MPCmin_{T-n+1}^{-1}, \qquad \MPCmax_{T-n}^{-1} = 1+\left(\MPSmin\right) \MPCmax_{T-n+1}^{-1}.
\end{equation}
\item We have $\lim\limits_{n \rightarrow \infty }\MPCmax_{T-n} = \MPCmax>0$.
Moreover, if \hyperlink{RIC}{return impatience} (Assumption \ref{ass:RIC}) holds, then $\lim\limits_{n \rightarrow \infty}\MPCmin_{T-n} = \MPCmin = 1- \RPFac>0$.
\end{enumerate}
\end{lemma}
\begin{proof}\let\qed\relax
See Appendix~\ref{sec:MPCiterproofs} for the proof.
\end{proof}
The MPC bound as market resources approach infinity is easy to understand.
Recall that $\bar{\cFunc}$ from the perfect foresight case will be an upper bound in the problem with uncertainty; analogously, $\MPCmin$ becomes the MPC's lower bound.
As the \textit{proportion} of consumption that will be financed out of human wealth approaches zero, the proportional difference between the solution to the model with uncertainty and the perfect foresight model shrinks to zero.
% AS to AS: The second sentence above comes out of nowhere. Can we link to a formal result? The stuff that was in the start of the "properties of the consumption function section"?
To understand the maximal limiting MPC, the essence of the argument is that as market resources approach zero, the overriding consideration that limits consumption is the (recursive) fear of the zero-income events --- this is why the probability of the zero income event $\pZero$ appears in the expression for the maximal MPC.
\hyperlink{WRIC}{Weak return impatience} is too weak to guarantee a lower bound on the share of consumption to market resources; it merely prevents the upper bound on the share of consumption to market resources from approaching zero.
Weak return impatience thereby prevents a situation where \textit{everyone} consumes an arbitrarily small share of current market resources as the terminal period recedes.
This insight plays a key role in the proof for the existence of a non-degenerate solution in what follows.
\begin{comment}
Next, define the `Value of Autarky Factor:'\hypertarget{VAFacDefn}{}
$DiscFac \PermGroFac^{1-\CRRA}\Ex(\permShk^{1-\CRRA})$
\end{align}
\end{comment}
\hypertarget{Conditions-Under-Which-the-Problem-Defines-a-Contraction-Mapping}{}
\subsubsection{Existence of Limiting Non-degenerate Solution}\label{subsubsec:eventuallyCauchy}
Let $\mathcal{C}(\Reals_{++},\Reals)$ be the space of continuous functions from $\Reals_{++}$ to $\Reals$.
To address the challenges posed by unbounded state-spaces, Boyd~\citeyearpar{jboydWeighted} provided a weighted contraction mapping theorem.
Our strategy is to use this approach to first show that while the \hyperlink{Stationary-Bellman-Operator}{stationary operator} $\TMap$ may be undefined on a suitable Banach space (recall Remark \ref{remark:notCompact}), operators defining each period's problem (which we define below) will be contractions on a space of continuous functions with a finite weighted norm.
We then show the sequence of finite horizon value functions given by Problem \eqref{eq:veqnNrmRecBellman} generates a Cauchy sequence; since the weighted norm space is complete, the sequence of value functions converges to a non-degenerate solution in $\mathcal{C}(\Reals_{++},\Reals)$.
\begin{definition}
Fix $\fFunc$ such that $\fFunc \in \mathcal{C}(\Reals_{++},\Reals)$ and let $\boundFunc$ be a function such that $\boundFunc\in \mathcal{C}(\Reals_{++},\Reals)$ and $\boundFunc >0$. The function $\fFunc$ will be $\boundFunc$-bounded if the $\boundFunc$-norm of $\fFunc$, given by
\begin{equation}
\Vert \fFunc\Vert _{\boundFunc }=\sup_{s\in \Reals_{++}}\left[ \frac{|\fFunc(s)|}{\boundFunc (s)}\right],
\label{eq:phinorm}
\end{equation}%
is finite.
We will call $\mathcal{C}_{\boundFunc}(\Reals_{++},\Reals)$ the subspace of functions in $\mathcal{C}(\Reals_{++},\Reals)$ that are $\boundFunc$-bounded.
\end{definition}
We define the weighting function as
%
\begin{verbatimwrite}{\econtexRoot/Equations/boundFunc}
\begin{equation}
\boundFunc(x) = \zeta + x^{1-\gamma},
\end{equation}
\end{verbatimwrite}
\input{Equations/boundFunc}
where $\zeta \in \Reals_{++}$ is a constant derived from the model primitives and the upper and lower bound on the consumption share (see Claim \ref{rem:shnkrdef} in Appendix \ref{sec:Tcontractionmapping} for the parametrization of $\zeta$).
Next, for any lower bound $\MPCminInf$ and upper-bound $\MPCmaxInf$ on the share of consumption to market resources, define the `MPC bounded Bellman operator' $\TMap^{\MPCminInf, \MPCmaxInf}$, with \textit{$\TMap^{\MPCminInf, \MPCmaxInf}:\mathcal{C}_{\boundFunc }\left( \Reals_{++},\Reals\right) \rightarrow \mathcal{C}_{\boundFunc }\left( \Reals_{++},\Reals\right) $}, as:
%
\begin{multline}
\TMap^{\MPCminInf, \MPCmaxInf} \fFunc(m) \\ = \max_{\cNrm \in
[\MPCminInf \mNrm, \MPCmaxInf \mNrm]
} \left\{\uFunc(c) + \DiscFac\Ex\Rnd{\PermGroFac}^{1-\CRRA}\fFunc(\RNrmByGRnd(m - c) + \tranShkAll)\right\}, \,\, \mNrm\in \Reals_{++}, \fFunc\in \mathcal{C}_{\boundFunc }\left(\Reals_{++},\Reals\right).
\end{multline}
The value functions defined by Problem \eqref{eq:veqnNrmRecBellman} will satisfy $\vFunc_{t} = \TMap^{\MPCmin_{t}, \MPCmax_{t}}\vFunc_{t+1}$ for each period $t$, since consumption shares are bounded by the minimal and maximal MPCs (Lemma \ref{lemm:MPC} and Equation \eqref{eq:cBounds}).
We now show the operator $\TMap^{\MPCminInf, \MPCmaxInf}$ is a contraction on $\mathcal{C}_{\boundFunc }\left( \Reals_{++},\Reals\right)$ for a suitably narrow interval $[\MPCminInf, \MPCmaxInf]$.
\begin{theorem}(Contraction Mapping Under Consumption Bounds).
\label{thm:cmap}
If \hyperlink{WRIC}{weak return impatience} (Assumption \ref{ass:WRIC}) and \hyperlink{FVAC}{finite value of autarky} (Assumption \ref{ass:FVAC}) hold, then there exists $k$ and $\alpha\in (0,1)$ such that for all $[\MPCminInf, \MPCmaxInf]$ with $\MPCmax_{T-k}\geq \MPCmaxInf> \MPCminInf>0$, $\TMap^{\MPCminInf, \MPCmaxInf}$ is a contraction with modulus $\alpha$.
\end{theorem}
\begin{proof}
See Appendix \ref{sec:Tcontractionmapping} for the proof.
\end{proof}
The theorem says eventually the maximal MPCs will be small enough such that the Bellman operators generating the sequence of finite horizon value functions given by \eqref{eq:veqnNrmRecBellman} are contraction maps.
We can now relate the sequence of contraction maps to the limiting solution defined in Section \ref{subsubsec:ratio}.
\hypertarget{Sufficient-Conditions-For-non-degenerate-Solution}{}
\begin{theorem}(Existence of Non-degenerate Solution).
\label{thm:convgtobellman}
If \hyperlink{WRIC}{weak return impatience} (Assumption \ref{ass:WRIC}) and \hyperlink{FVAC}{finite value of autarky} (Assumption \ref{ass:FVAC}) hold, then:
%
\begin{enumerate}[label=(\roman*)]
\item There exists $k\in \mathbb{N}$ such that a) for all $n>k$ and $\MPCminInf$ with $0<\MPCminInf<\MPCmax_{T-n}$, $\TMap^{\MPCminInf, \MPCmax_{T-n}}$ is a contraction with modulus $\Shrinker<1$ and b) the sequence $\left\{\vFunc_{T-n}\right\}_{n=0}^{\infty}$ converges point-wise to $\vFunc \in \mathcal{C}_{\boundFunc}(\Reals_{++},\Reals)$.
\item The function $\vFunc$ is a fixed point of $\TMap$ and there exists a measurable policy function, $\cFunc$, such that $\cFunc\colon \Reals_{++}\rightarrow \Reals$ and:
\begin{equation}\label{eq:stationarybellman}
\TMap\vFunc(m) = \uFunc(\cFunc(m)) + \DiscFac\Ex \Rnd{\PermGroFac}^{1-\CRRA}\vFunc(\RNrmByGRnd(m-\cFunc(m)) + \tranShkAll) , \qquad m\in \Reals_{++}.
\end{equation}
\item The sequence $\left\{\cFunc_{T-n}\right\}_{n=0}^{\infty}$ converges point-wise to $\cFunc$ and $\cFunc$ and $\vFunc$ are a \hyperlink{Definition-of-a-non-degenerate-Solution}{limiting non-degenerate solution}.
\end{enumerate}
\end{theorem}
\begin{proof}
Item (i.)(a.) follows from Theorem \ref{thm:cmap}, since $0<\MPCminInf<\MPCmax_{T-n}$ and for each $t$, $\MPCmax_{T-n}\leq \MPCmax_{T-k}$ by Lemma \ref{lemm:MPC}.
We now prove Item (i.)(b.), that $\left\{\vFunc_{T-n}\right\}_{n=0}^{\infty}$ converges point-wise to a \hyperlink{Definition-of-a-non-degenerate-Solution}{limiting non-degenerate solution} $\vFunc$.
In the proof, to streamline the notation, we define $t_{n}\colon = T - n$.
Now, for all $n>k+2$, $\vFunc_{t_{n}} = \TMap^{\MPCmin_{t_{n}}, \MPCmax_{t_{n}}}\vFunc_{t_{n-1}}$ holds by definition of Problem \eqref{eq:veqnNrmRecBellman}.
Moreover, since $\MPCmax_{t_{n-1}}\geq \MPCmax_{t_{n}}$ by Lemma \ref{lemm:MPC}, we have:
%
\begin{equation*}
\vFunc_{t_{n}} = \TMap^{\MPCmin_{t_{n}}, \MPCmax_{t_{n-1}}}\vFunc_{t_{n-1}},
\end{equation*}
%
and since $\MPCmin_{t_{n}}\leq \MPCmin_{t_{n-1}}$, we have:
%
\begin{align*}
\vFunc_{t_{n-1}} & = \TMap^{\MPCmin_{t_{n-1}}, \MPCmax_{t_{n-1}}}\vFunc_{n-2}\\ & = \TMap^{\MPCmin_{t_{n}}, \MPCmax_{t_{n-1}}}\vFunc_{t_{n-2}}.
\end{align*}
Next, take the $\boundFunc$-norm distance between $\vFunc_{t_{n}}$ and $\vFunc_{t_{n-1}}$, and note $\TMap^{\MPCmin_{t_{n}}, \MPCmax_{t_{n-1}}}$ is a contraction.
As such, the sequence of finite horizon value functions satisfy:
%
\begin{equation*}
\Vert\vFunc_{t_{n}} - \vFunc_{t_{n-1}}\Vert_{\boundFunc} = \Vert\TMap^{\MPCmin_{t_{n}}, \MPCmax_{t_{n-1}}}\vFunc_{t_{n-1}} - \TMap^{\MPCmin_{t_{n}}, \MPCmax_{t_{n-1}}}\vFunc_{t_{n-2}}\Vert_{\boundFunc} \leq \Shrinker \Vert \vFunc_{t_{n-1}} - \vFunc_{t_{n-2}}\Vert_{\boundFunc}.
\end{equation*}
%
As such, $\Vert \vFunc_{t_{n}} - \vFunc_{t_{n-1}}\Vert_{\boundFunc } \leq \Shrinker \Vert \vFunc_{t_{n-1}} - \vFunc_{t_{n-2}}\Vert_{\boundFunc } $; because $n$ is arbitrary and $\alpha$ holds for all $n$ by Theorem \ref{thm:cmap}, this is a sufficient condition for $\left\{\vFunc_{T-n}\right\}_{n=k+2}^{\infty}$ to be a Cauchy sequence.
Since $\mathcal{C}_{\boundFunc }\left(\Reals_{++},\Reals\right) $ is a complete metric space, and $\vFunc_{t_{n-2}} \in \mathcal{C}_{\boundFunc }\left(\Reals_{++},\Reals\right)$ for each $n$, $\vFunc_{t_{n}}$ converges to $v$, with $v\in \mathcal{C}_{\boundFunc }\left(\Reals_{++},\Reals\right)$.
The proof for Item (i) and Item (ii) is continued in Appendix \ref{sec:Tcontractionmapping}.)
\end{proof}
The proof above shows that the sequence of value functions produced by the iteration of the per-period Bellman operators $\TMap^{\MPCmin_{T-n}, \MPCmax_{T-n}}$ will be a Cauchy sequence converging to the limiting solution.
Due to \hyperlink{WRIC}{weak return impatience}, the upper bound on the per-period consumption converges to a strictly positive share of market resources, preventing consumption from converging to zero.
\begin{remark}
Under \hyperlink{RIC}{return impatience}, $\MPCmin_{T-n}\geq \MPCmin>0$ for all $n$, and thus for $k\in \mathbb{N}$ large enough, $\TMap^{\MPCmin, \MPCmax_{T-k}}$ will be a stationary contraction map and we will have $\vFunc_{T-n} = \TMap^{\MPCmin, \MPCmax_{T-k}}\vFunc_{T-n+1}$ for all $n>k$. However, without \hyperlink{RIC}{return impatience}, $\MPCmin = 0$ and $\TMap^{0, \MPC_{T-k}}$ will not be a well-defined operator from $\mathcal{C}_{\boundFunc }\left(\Reals_{++},\Reals\right)$ to $\mathcal{C}_{\boundFunc }\left(\Reals_{++},\Reals\right)$, even for $k$ large enough (recall Section \ref{subsubsec:challengesDP}).
\end{remark}
Finite value of autarky is the second assumption required to show existence of limiting solutions and guarantees the value is finite (in levels) for a consumer who spent exactly their permanent income every period (see Section \ref{subsec:TheModelUncertainty}).
The intuition for the finite value of autarky condition is that, with an infinite-horizon, with any strictly positive initial amount of bank balances $\bNrm_{0}$, in the limit your value can always be made greater than you would get by consuming exactly the sustainable amount (say, by consuming $(\rfree/\Rfree)\bNrm_{0}-\epsilon$ for some arbitrarily small $\epsilon>0$).
\begin{remark}\label{remark:cStatStrctPos}
Since $\MPCmax m \geq \cFunc_{T-n}(\mNrm)\geq \MPCmin m$ and $\cFunc_{T-n}$ converges point-wise to $\cFunc$, $\MPCmax m \geq \cFunc(\mNrm)\geq \MPCmin m$. Moreover, since $\cFunc$ satisfies Equation \eqref{eq:stationarybellman} and $\vFunc \in \mathcal{C}_{\boundFunc }\left(\Reals_{++},\Reals\right) $, $\cFunc(\mNrm)>0$ for $\mNrm>0$.
\end{remark}
Finally, we verify that the converged non-degenerate consumption functions satisfies the same marginal propensities to consume the per-period consumption functions.
\begin{lemma}\label{lemma:MPCBoundsConvg}
If \hyperlink{WRIC}{weak return impatience} (Assumption \ref{ass:WRIC}) holds, then $\lim\limits_{m\rightarrow \infty} \cFunc (m)/m =\MPCmin m$ and $\lim\limits_{m\rightarrow 0} \cFunc (m)/m =\MPCmax m$.
\end{lemma}
\begin{proof}\let\qed\relax
See Appendix~\ref{sec:appxconvgC} for the proof.
\end{proof}
\hypertarget{The-Liquidity-Constrained-Solution-as-a-Limit}{}
\subsubsection{The Liquidity Constrained Solution as a Limit}\label{subsubsec:deatonIsLimit}
Recall the common assumption \citep{deatonLiqConstr,aiyagari:ge, lsIncFluct, mstIncFluct} of a strictly positive minimum value of income and a non-trivial artificial liquidity constraint, namely $\aNrm_{t}\geq 0$.
We will refer to the set-up from Section \ref{subsec:Setup}, with Assumption \ref{thm:convgtobellman} modified so $\pZero=0$ as the ``liquidity constrained problem.'' Let $\cFunc_{t}(\bullet;\pZero)$ be the consumption function for a problem where Assumption \ref{ass:shocks} holds for a given fixed $\pZero$, with $\pZero>0$.
Moreover, let $\cnstr{\cFunc}_{t}$ be the limiting consumption function for the liquidity constrained problem (note that the liquidity constraint $\cNrm_{t}\leq \mNrm_{t}$, or $\aNrm_{t}\geq 0$, becomes relevant only when $\pZero= 0$).
The discussion in Appendix \ref{sec:LiqConstrAsLimit} shows how an finite-horizon solution to the liquidity constrained problem, $\cnstr{\cFunc}_{t}$ , is the limit of the problems as the probability $\pZero$ of the zero-income event approaches zero.
Intuitively, if we impose the artificial constraint without changing $\pZero$ and maintain $\pZero>0$, it would not affect behavior.
This is because the possibility of earning zero income over the remaining horizon already prevents the consumer from ending the period with zero assets.
For precautionary reasons, the consumer will save something.
However, the \textit{extent} to which the consumer feels the need to make this precautionary provision depends on the \textit{probability} that it will turn out to matter.
As $\pZero \rightarrow 0$, the precautionary saving induced by the zero-income events approaches zero, and ``zero'' is the amount of precautionary saving that would be induced by a zero-probability event by the impatient liquidity constrained consumer.
See Appendix~\ref{sec:LiqConstrAsLimit} for the formal proof.
\hypertarget{Analysis of the Converged Consumption Function}{}
\section{Individual Buffer Stock Stability}\label{sec:individStability}
In this section we analyse two notions of stability which will be useful for studying either an individual or a population of individuals who behave according to the converged consumption rule.
Consider an individual who at time $t$ holds normalized and non-normalized market resources $\mNrm_{t}$ and $\mLvl_{t}$ and follows the converged decision function $\cFunc$.
The time-$t$ consumption for the consumer will be $\cNrm_{t} = \cFunc(\mNrm_{t})$ and the time $t+1$ market resources will be a random variable $\mNrm_{t+1} = \RNrmByGRnd_{t+1}(\mNrm_{t} - \cFunc(\mNrm_{t})) + \tranShkAll_{t+1}$.\footnote{None of the arguments in either of the two prior sections depended on the assumption that the consumption functions had converged.
With more cumbersome notation, each derivation could have been replaced by the corresponding finite-horizon versions.
This strongly suggests that it should be possible to extend the circumstances under which the problem can be shown to define a contraction mapping to the union of the parameter values under which \{\RIC,\FHWC\} hold and \{\FVAC,\WRIC\} hold.
That extension is not necessary for our purposes here, so we leave it for future work.}
At the individual level, we are interested in whether the current level of market resources is above or below a `target' level such that the magnitude of the precautionary motive (which causes a consumer to save) exactly balances the impatience motive (which makes them want to dissave).
At the individual `target', the expected market resources ratio in the next period, \textit{conditioned on the current market resources ratio}, will be the same as the ratio in the current period.
The intensifying strength of the precautionary motive with decreasing market resources can ensure stability of the target.
Below the target, the urgency to save due to the precautionary motive leads to an expected rise in market resources.
Conversely, above the target, impatience prevails, leading to an expected reduction of market resources.
In this way, the `target' essentially defines the desired `buffer stock' of resources for the consumer.
To help motivate the theoretical results concerning existence of a target level of market resources, Figure~\ref{fig:cNrmTargetFig} shows the expected growth factors for consumption, the level of market resources, and the market resources to permanent income ratio, $\Ex_{t}[\cLvl_{t+1}/\cLvl_{t}]$, $\Ex_{t}[\mLvl_{t+1}/\mLvl_{t}]$, and $\Ex_{t}[\mNrm_{t+1}/\mNrm_{t}]$.
The figure is generated using parameters discussed in Section \ref{sec:GICdiscussion}, Table \ref{table:Calibration}.
First, the figure shows how as $\mNrm_{t} \rightarrow \infty$ the expected consumption growth factor goes to ${\APFac}$, indicated by the lower bound in Figure~\ref{fig:cNrmTargetFig}.
Moreover, as $\mNrm_{t}$ approaches zero the consumption growth factor approaches $\infty$.
The following proposition establishes the asymptotic growth factors formally.
\begin{proposition}\label{prop:convgGrowth}\hypertarget{LimitsAsmtToZero}{}
We have $\lim\limits_{\mNrm_{t} \rightarrow \infty} \Ex_{t}[\cLvl_{t+1}/\cLvl_{t}] = {\APFac}$ and $\lim\limits_{\mNrm_{t} \rightarrow 0} \Ex_{t}[\cLvl_{t+1}/\cLvl_{t}] = \infty$.
\end{proposition}
\begin{proof}\let\qed\relax
See Appendix \ref{subsec:AppxCgrowthFac} for the proof.
\end{proof}
Next, consider the implications of Figure~\ref{fig:cNrmTargetFig} for individual stability.
The figure shows a value of the market resources ratio, $\mNrm_{t} = \mBalLvl$, at which point the expected growth factor of the level of market resources $\mLvl$ matches the expected growth factor of permanent income $\PermGroFac$.
A distinct and larger target ratio, $\mTrgNrm$, also exists.
At this ratio, $\Ex_{t}[\mNrm_{t+1}/\mNrm_{t}]=1$, and the expected growth factor of consumption is less than $\PermGroFac$.
Importantly, at the individual level, this model does not have a single $\mNrm$ at which $\permLvl$, $\mLvl$ and $\cLvl$ are all expected to grow at the same rate.
Yet, when we aggregate across individuals, balanced growth paths can exist, even if there does not exist a target ratio where $\Ex_{t}[\mNrm_{t+1}/\mNrm_{t}]=1$.
\begin{comment}
Third (Figure~\ref{fig:cNrmTargetFig}), there are two special values of $\mNrm$, which we will call the `individual balanced growth' point $\mBalLvl$ because it is the point where expected consumption growth and expected permanent income growth are balanced, and the `individual target' $\mTrgNrm$ such that if $\mNrm_t = \mTrgNrm$ then $\Ex_t [{\mNrm}_{t+1}] = \mNrm_t$.
%As indicated by the arrows of motion on the $\Ex_{t}[\cLvl_{t+1}/\cLvl_{t}]$ curve, the model's dynamics are `stable' around this target in the sense that if $\mNrm_{t} < \mTrgNrm$ then $\mNrm$ will rise (in expectation), while if $\mNrm_{t} > \mTrgNrm$, it will fall (in expectation).Fourth (Figure~\ref{fig:cNrmTargetFig}), at the market resources target $\mTrgNrm$, the expected rate of growth of consumption is slightly less than the expected growth factor
of permanent noncapital income.
(The individual consumer does not expect `balanced growth' at $\mTrgNrm$).
The final proposition suggested by Figure~\ref{fig:cNrmTargetFig} is that the expected consumption growth factor is declining in the level of the market resources to permanent ratio $\mNrm_{t}$.
This turns out to be true in the absence of permanent shocks, but in extreme cases it can be false if permanent shocks are present.\footnote{Throughout the remaining analysis I make a final assumption that is not strictly justified by the foregoing.
We have seen that the finite-horizon consumption functions $\usual{\cFunc}_{t_{n}}(\mNrm)$ are twice continuously differentiable and strictly concave, and that they converge to a continuous function $\usual{\cFunc}(\mNrm)$.
It does not strictly follow that the limiting function $\usual{\cFunc}(\mNrm)$ is twice continuously differentiable, but I will assume that it is.}
\end{comment}
\providecommand{\figName}{cNrmTargetFig}
\providecommand{\figFile}{\figName} % and on filename
% \figName allows generic definition of hypertargets based on title of figure
\renewcommand{\figName}{cNrmTargetFig}
\hypertarget{\figFile}{}
\input{Figures/cNrmTargetFig}
\begin{comment}
Of course, the constraint never becomes irrelevant if human wealth is
infinite.
We ruled out infinite human wealth at the beginning of this
section by assuming $\Rfree> \PermGroFac$.
If this finite human wealth
condition does not hold, it is possible to show that for any finite
horizon consumer the marginal propensity to consume approaches the
finite-horizon perfect foresight MPC as wealth approaches infinity.
However, as the horizon gets longer, the perfect foresight MPC
approaches zero.
It can be shown therefore that the limiting MPC for
the converged consumption function approaches (but never reaches)
zero.
(This is why we chose $\MPCminmin=0$ if the \FHWC~fails
in the proofs above.)
\end{comment}
%\end{document}\endinput
\hypertarget{onetarget}{}
\hypertarget{Unique-Stable-Points}{}
\subsection{Unique `Stable' Points}\label{subsec:onetarget}\hypertarget{TheoremTarget}{}
One kind of `stable' point is a `target' value $\mTrgNrm$ such that if $\mNrm_{t}=\mTrgNrm$, then $\Ex_{t}[\mNrm_{t+1}]=\mNrm_{t}$.
Existence of such a target requires the \hyperlink{GICMod}{strong growth impatience} condition.
\begin{verbatimwrite}{Equations/TheoremMTargetIsStable}
\begin{theorem}\label{thm:target} (Individual Market-Resources-to-Permanent-Income Ratio Target).
% Don't define it if already defined
Consider the problem defined in Section~\ref{subsec:Setup}.
If \hyperlink{WRIC}{weak return impatience} (Assumption \ref{ass:WRIC}), \hyperlink{FVAC}{finite value of autarky} (Assumption \ref{ass:FVAC}) and \hyperlink{GICMod}{strong growth impatience} (Assumption \ref{ass:GICMod}) hold, then there exists $\mTrgNrm$, with $\mTrgNrm>0$, such that:
\begin{equation}
\Ex_t [{\mNrm}_{t+1}/\mNrm_t] = 1 \mbox{~if~} \mNrm_t = \mTrgNrm,
\label{eq:mTarget} % Don't define it if already defined
\end{equation}
and,
\begin{equation}
\label{eq:stability} % Don't define it if already defined
\begin{split}
\forall {\mNrm}_t\in(0,\mTrgNrm), \,\,& \Ex_t [{\mNrm}_{t+1}] > {\mNrm}_t \\
\forall {\mNrm}_t\in(\mTrgNrm,\infty), \,\,& \Ex_t [{\mNrm}_{t+1}] < {\mNrm}_t.
\end{split}
\end{equation}
\end{theorem}
\end{verbatimwrite}
\input{Equations/TheoremMTargetIsStable}
\begin{proof}\let\qed\relax
See Appendix \ref{subsubsec:AppxIndividTarget} for the proof.
\end{proof}
If $\mTrgNrm$ satisfies \eqref{eq:stability}, we say $\mTrgNrm$ is a point of `stability'.
%\end{document}\endinput
\hypertarget{mTargImplicit}{}
Since $\mNrm_{t+1}= (\mNrm_{t}-\cFunc(\mNrm_{t}))\RNrmByGRnd_{t+1} +\tranShkAll_{t+1}$, the implicit equation for $\mTrgNrm$ becomes:
%
\begin{equation} \label{eq:mTargImplicit}
\begin{split}
\Ex_{t} [(\mTrgNrm-\cFunc(\mTrgNrm))\RNrmByGRnd_{t+1}+\tranShkAll_{t+1}] & = \mTrgNrm \\ (\mTrgNrm-\cFunc(\mTrgNrm))\underbrace{\RNrmByG\Ex_{t}[\permShk^{-1}]}_{\colon = \bar{\RNrmByGRnd}}+1 & = \mTrgNrm .
\end{split}
\end{equation}
\hypertarget{Collective-Stability}{}
\hypertarget{pseudo-steady-state}{}
The market-resources-to-permanent-income ratio target is the most restrictive among several competing definitions of stability.
Our least restrictive definition of `stability' derives from a traditional aggregate question in macro models: whether or not there is a `balanced growth' equilibrium in which aggregate variables (income, consumption, market resources) all grow by the same factor $\PermGroFac$.
In particular, if \hyperlink{GIC}{growth impatience} holds, the problem will exhibit a balanced-growth `pseudo-steady-state' point, by which we mean that there is some ${\mBalLvl}$ such that if $\mNrm_{t}>{\mBalLvl}$, then $\Ex_{t}[\mLvl_{t+1}/\mLvl_{t}] < \PermGroFac$.\hypertarget{balgrostable}{}
\hypertarget{balgrostableSolve}{}
Conversely if $\mNrm_{t}<{\mBalLvl}$ then $\Ex_{t}[\mLvl_{t+1}/\mLvl_{t}] > \PermGroFac$.
The target $\mBalLvl$ will be such that $\mLvl$ growth matches $\PermGroFac$, allowing us to write the implicit equation for $\mBalLvl$ as follows:
%
\begin{equation}\label{eq:balgrostable}
\begin{split}
\Ex_{t}[\mLvl_{t+1}]/\mLvl_{t} & =\Ex_{t}[\permLvl_{t+1}]/\permLvl_{t}
\\ \Ex_{t}[\mNrm_{t+1}\PermGroFac\permShk_{t+1}\permLvl_{t}]/(\mNrm_{t}\permLvl_{t}) & =\Ex_{t}[\permLvl_{t}\PermGroFac\permShk_{t+1}]/\permLvl_{t}
\\ \Ex_{t}\left[\permShk_{t+1}\underbrace{\left((\mNrm_{t}-\usual{\cFunc}(\mNrm_{t})\Rfree/(\PermGroFac\permShk_{t+1}))+\tranShkAll_{t+1}\right)}_{\mNrm_{t+1}}\right]/\mNrm_{t} & = 1
\\
\Ex_{t}\left[(\mBalLvl-\usual{\cFunc}(\mBalLvl))\overbrace{\Rfree/\PermGroFac}^{\RNrmByG}+\permShk_{t+1}\tranShkAll_{t+1}\right] & = \mBalLvl
\\ (\mBalLvl-\usual{\cFunc}(\mBalLvl))\RNrmByG + 1 & = \mBalLvl .
\end{split}
\end{equation}
The only difference between~\eqref{eq:balgrostable} and~\eqref{eq:mTargImplicit} is the substitution of $\RNrmByG$ for $\bar{\RNrmByGRnd}$.\footnote{A third `stable point' is the $\mBalLog$ where $\Ex_{t}[\log \mLvl_{t+1}] = \log \PermGroFac \mLvl_{t}$; this can be conveniently rewritten as $\Ex_{t}\left[\log\left((\mBalLog-\usual{\cFunc}(\mBalLog))\RNrmByGRnd+\permShk_{t+1}\tranShkAll_{t+1}\right)\right] = \log \mBalLog_{t}$.
Because the expectation of the log of a stochastic variable is less than the log of the expectation, if a solution for $\mBalLog$ exists it will satisfy $\mBalLog > \mBalLvl$; in turn, if $\mTrgNrm$ exists, $\mTrgNrm>\mBalLog$.
The target $\mBalLog$ is guaranteed to exist when the \hyperlink{GICSdl}{log growth impatience} condition is satisfied (see below).
For our purposes, little would be gained by an analysis of this point parallel to those of the other points of stability; but to accommodate potential practical uses, the {\ARKurl} toolkit computes the value of this point (when it exists) as \texttt{mBalLog}.}$^{,}$\footnote{Our choice to call to this the individual problem's `individual balanced-growth pseudo-steady-state' $\mBalLvl$ is motivated by what happens in the case where all draws of all future shocks just happen to take on their expected value of 1.0.
(They unexpectedly always take on their expected values).
In that infinitely improbable case, the economy \textit{would} exhibit balanced growth:
\begin{align*}
\Ex_{t}[\mNrm_{t+1}/\mNrm_{t}|\permShk_{t+1}=\tranShkAll_{t+1}=1] = \frac{\PermGroFac \left((\mBalLvl-\cFunc(\mBalLvl))\RNrmByG + 1 \right)}{\mNrm} = \PermGroFac.
\end{align*}}
%Theorem~\ref{thm:MSSBalExists}~formally states the relevant proposition.
Under the weaker \hyperlink{GIC}{growth impatience} condition, we can verify the existence of this pseudo-steady-state market resources to permanent income ratio, $\mBalLvl$.
\begin{verbatimwrite}{Equations/TheoremMSSBalExists}
\begin{theorem}(Individual Balanced-Growth `Pseudo Steady State').
\labelsafe{thm:MSSBalExists} % Don't define it if already defined
Consider the problem defined in Section~\ref{subsec:Setup}.
If \hyperlink{WRIC}{weak return impatience} (Assumption \ref{ass:WRIC}), \hyperlink{FVAC}{finite value of autarky} (Assumption \ref{ass:FVAC}) and \hyperlink{GIC}{growth impatience} (Assumption \ref{ass:GICRaw}) hold, then there exists a unique $\mBalLvl$, with $\mBalLvl>0$ such that:
\begin{equation}
\Ex_t [\permShk_{t+1}{\mNrm}_{t+1}/\mNrm_t] = 1 \mbox{~if~} \mNrm_t = \mBalLvl.
\label{eq:mBalLvl}
\end{equation}
Moreover, $\mBalLvl$ is a point of stability in the sense that:
\begin{equation}
\label{eq:stabilityStE}
\begin{split}
\forall {\mNrm}_t\in(0,\mBalLvl), \,\,& \Ex_{t}[\mLvl_{t+1}]/\mLvl_{t} > \PermGroFac \\
\forall {\mNrm}_t\in(\mBalLvl,\infty), \,\,& \Ex_{t}[\mLvl_{t+1}]/\mLvl_{t} < \PermGroFac.
\end{split}
\end{equation}
\end{theorem}
\end{verbatimwrite}
\input{Equations/TheoremMSSBalExists}
\begin{proof}
See Appendix \ref{subsubsec:AppxPseudoSS} for the proof.
\end{proof}
\begin{comment}
\hypertarget{log-pseudo-steady-state}{}
\subsubsection{The expected `log-pseudo steady state'}\label{subsubsec:logpseudosteadystate}
A final point of stability will be indicated by a $\sim$ accent; this is the $\mNrm$ at which the expectation of $\log \mLvl$ is unchanging.
\begin{verbatimwrite}{Equations/TheoremGroIsStable}
\begin{theorem}\label{thm:TheoremGroIsStable}{}{\label{thm:TheoremGroIsStable}}
For the non-degenerate solution to Section~\ref{subsec:Setup}'s problem when {\FVAC}, {\WRIC}, and {\GICRaw} all hold, there exists a unique cash-on-hand-to-permanent-income ratio $\mBalLvl>0$ such that
\begin{equation}
\Ex_t [\log {\mLvl}_{t+1} ] = \log \mLvl_t \mbox{~if~} \mLvl_t = \mBalLvl.
\label{eq:mTarget}
\end{equation}
Moreover, $\mBalLvl$ is a point of stability in the sense that
\begin{equation} \label{eq:stabilityLog}
\begin{split}
\forall {\mNrm}_t\in(0,\mBalLvl), \,\,& \Ex_t [\log {\mLvl}_{t+1}] > \log {\mLvl}_t \\
\forall {\mNrm}_t\in(\mBalLvl,\infty), \,\,& \Ex_t [\log {\mLvl}_{t+1}] < \log {\mLvl}_t.
\end{split}
\end{equation}
\end{theorem}
\end{verbatimwrite}
\input{Equations/TheoremGroIsStable}
with two associated Lemmas demonstrating that $\mBalLvl < \mBalLog$ and $\mBalLvl < \$\mTrgNrm$.
\end{comment}
\subsection{Example With Balanced-Growth \texorpdfstring{$\mBalLvl$}{m} But No Target~\texorpdfstring{$\mTrgNrm$}{m}}
Because the equations defining target and pseudo-steady-state $\mNrm$,~\eqref{eq:mTargImplicit} and~\eqref{eq:balgrostable}, differ only by substitution of $\RNrmByG$ for $\bar{\RNrmByGRnd}=\RNrmByG \Ex[\permShk^{-1}]$, if there are no permanent shocks ($\permShk \equiv 1$), the conditions are identical.
For many parameterizations (e.g., under the baseline parameter values used for constructing figure~\ref{fig:cNrmTargetFig}), $\mTrgNrm$ and $\mBalLvl$ will not differ much.
\renewcommand{\figFile}{GICModFailsButGICRawHolds}
\hypertarget{\figFile}{}
\input{Figures/GICModFailsButGICRawHolds}
An illuminating exception is exhibited in Figure~\ref{fig:GICModFailsButGICRawHolds}, which modifies the baseline parameter values by quadrupling the variance of the permanent shocks, enough to cause failure of \hyperlink{GICMod}{strong growth impatience}; now there is no target level of market resources $\mTrgNrm$.
Nonetheless, the pseudo-steady-state still exists because it turns off realizations of the permanent shock.
It is tempting to conclude that the reason target $\mTrgNrm$ does not exist is that the increase in the size of the shocks induces a precautionary motive that increases the consumer's effective patience.
The interpretation is not correct because as market resources approach infinity, precautionary saving against noncapital income risk becomes negligible (as the proportion of consumption financed out of such income approaches zero).
The correct explanation is more prosaic: The increase in uncertainty boosts the expected uncertainty-modified rate of return factor from $\RNrmByG$ to $\bar{\RNrmByGRnd}>\RNrmByG$ which reflects the fact that in the presence of uncertainty the expectation of the inverse of the growth factor increases: $\PermGroFacAdj > \PermGroFac$.
That is, in the limit as $\mNrm \rightarrow \infty$ the increase in effective impatience reflected in $\GPFacMod < \GPFacRaw$ is entirely due to the certainty-equivalence growth adjustment, not to a (limiting) change in precaution.
In fact, the next section will show that an aggregate balanced growth equilibrium will exist even when realizations of the permanent shock are not turned off: The required condition for aggregate balanced growth is the regular \hyperlink{GIC}{growth impatience}, which ignores the magnitude of permanent shocks.\footnote{\cite{szeidlInvariant}'s impatience condition, discussed below, also tightens as uncertainty increases, but this is also not a consequence of a precaution-induced increase in patience -- it represents an increase in the tightness of the requirements of the `mixing condition' used in his proof.}
\begin{comment}
again, removed FHWC above since GIC holds.
double check.
\end{comment}
Before we get to the formal arguments, the key insight can be understood by considering an economy that starts, at date $t$, with the entire population at $\mNrm_{t}=\mBalLvl$, but then evolves according to the model's assumed dynamics between $t$ and $t+1$.
Equation~\eqref{eq:balgrostable} will still hold, so for this first period, at least, the economy will exhibit balanced growth: the growth factor for aggregate $\MLvl$ will match the growth factor for permanent income $\PermGroFac$.
It is true that there will be people for whom financial balances, $\bNrm_{t+1}$, where $\bNrm_{t+1} = \kNrm_{t+1}\Rfree/(\PermGroFac\permShk_{t+1})$, are boosted by a small draw of $\permShk_{t+1}$.
However, their contribution to the \textit{level} of the aggregate variable is given by $\bLvl_{t+1}=\bNrm_{t+1}\pLvl_{t}\permShk_{t+1}$, so their $\bNrm_{t+1}$ is reweighted by an amount that exactly unwinds that divisor-boosting.
This means that it is possible for the consumption-to-permanent-income ratio for every consumer to be small enough that their market resources ratio is expected to rise, and yet for the economy as a whole to exhibit a balanced growth equilibrium with a finite aggregate balanced growth steady state $\BalGroFac{\MNrm}$ (this is not numerically the same as the individual \hyperlink{pseudo-steady-state}{pseudo-steady-state} ratio $\mBalLvl$ because the problem's nonlinearities have consequences when aggregated).\footnote{Still, the pseudo-steady-state can be calculated from the policy function without any simulation, and therefore serves as a low-cost starting point for the numerical simulation process; see \href{https://econ-ark.org/materials/harmenberg-aggregation?launch}{Harmenberg-Aggregation} for an example.}
\begin{comment}
**** candidate for deletion****
\hypertarget{LimitsAsmtToInfty}{}
\subsection{Limits as \texorpdfstring{$\mNrm$}{m} Approaches Infinity}\label{subsec:LimitsAsmtToInfty}
Define
\begin{align*}
\Min{\cFunc}(\mNrm) & = \MPCmin \mNrm
\end{align*}
which is the solution to an infinite-horizon problem with no noncapital income ($\tranShkAll_{t+n} = 0~\forall~n\geq1$); clearly $\Min{\cFunc}(\mNrm) < \usual{\cFunc}(\mNrm)$, since allowing the possibility of future noncapital income cannot reduce current consumption.
Our imposition of the {\RIC} guarantees that $\MPCmin > 0$, so this solution satisfies our definition of nondegeneracy, and because this solution is always available it defines a lower bound on both the consumption and value functions.%\footnote{We will assume the \RIC~holds here and subsequently so that $\MPCmin > 0$; the situation is a bit more complex when the \RIC~does not hold. In that case the bound on consumption is given by the spending that would be undertaken by a consumer who faced binding liquidity constraints.}
Assuming the {\FHWC}~holds, the infinite-horizon perfect foresight solution~\eqref{eq:cFuncPFUnc} constitutes an upper bound on consumption in the presence of uncertainty, since the introduction of uncertainty strictly decreases the level of consumption at any $\mNrm$ (\cite{ckConcavity}).
Thus,
\begin{equation} \label{eq:lowerltupper}
\begin{split}
\Min{\cFunc}(\mNrm) < & \usual{\cFunc}(\mNrm) < \bar{\cFunc}(\mNrm) \\
1 < & \usual{\cFunc}(\mNrm)/\Min{\cFunc}(\mNrm) < \bar{\cFunc}(\mNrm)/\Min{\cFunc}(\mNrm).
\end{split}