forked from llorracc/BufferStockTheory
-
Notifications
You must be signed in to change notification settings - Fork 0
/
Introduction.tex
282 lines (211 loc) · 29.4 KB
/
Introduction.tex
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
61
62
63
64
65
66
67
68
69
70
71
72
73
74
75
76
77
78
79
80
81
82
83
84
85
86
87
88
89
90
91
92
93
94
95
96
97
98
99
100
101
102
103
104
105
106
107
108
109
110
111
112
113
114
115
116
117
118
119
120
121
122
123
124
125
126
127
128
129
130
131
132
133
134
135
136
137
138
139
140
141
142
143
144
145
146
147
148
149
150
151
152
153
154
155
156
157
158
159
160
161
162
163
164
165
166
167
168
169
170
171
172
173
174
175
176
177
178
179
180
181
182
183
184
185
186
187
188
189
190
191
192
193
194
195
196
197
198
199
200
201
202
203
204
205
206
207
208
209
210
211
212
213
214
215
216
217
218
219
220
221
222
223
224
225
226
227
228
229
230
231
232
233
234
235
236
237
238
239
240
241
242
243
244
245
246
247
248
249
250
251
252
253
254
255
256
257
258
259
260
261
262
263
264
265
266
267
268
269
270
271
272
273
274
275
276
277
278
279
280
281
282
\input{@resources/tex-add-search-paths} % allow latex to find custom stuff
% -*- mode: LaTeX; TeX-PDF-mode: t; -*-
\input{./.econtexRoot}\documentclass[BufferStockTheory]{subfiles}
\newcommand{\subname}{Introduction} % Needed for generic bib to work
%\input{\econtexRoot/@local/dir-paths} % get directory macros
\usepackage{econark-ifsubfile}
\usepackage{econark-xrsetup}
% if it's being compiled standalone, set up identity of the external
\compilingasstandalone{
\xrsetup{\econtexRoot/\texname}
}
% \begin{document}
% Section~\ref{subsubsec:deatonIsLimit})
% The first panel of Table~\ref{table:Required} summarizes: The PF-Unconstrained model has a nondegenerate limiting solution if we impose the {\RIC} and {\FHWC} (these conditions are necessary as well as sufficient).
% Together the {\PFFVAC} and the {\FHWC} imply the {\RIC}.
% \cite{carroll:death}
% \compilingasstandalone{
% \bibliography{Introduction}
% }
% \end{document}\endinput
\newcommand{\thankstext}{
The paper's results \href{https://\owner.github.io/nbreproduce}{can be automatically reproduced} using the {\ARKurl} toolkit, which can be cited per our references (\cite{carroll_et_al-proc-scipy-2018}); for reference to the toolkit itself see \href{https://econ-ark.org/acknowledging}{Acknowledging Econ-ARK}.
Thanks to the \href{https://consumerfinance.gov}{Consumer Financial Protection Bureau} for funding the original creation of the {\ARKurl} toolkit; and to the \href{https://sloan.org}{Sloan Foundation} for funding Econ-ARK's \href{https://sloan.org/grant-detail/8071}{extensive åfurther development} that brought it to the point where it could be used for this project.
The toolkit can be cited with its digital object identifier, \href{https://doi.org/10.5281/zenodo.1001067}{10.5281/zenodo.1001067}, as is done in the paper's own references as \cite{carroll_et_al-proc-scipy-2018}.
Thanks to Will Du, James Feigenbaum, Joseph Kaboski, Miles Kimball, Qingyin Ma, Misuzu Otsuka, Damiano Sandri, John Stachurski, Adam Szeidl, Alexis Akira Toda, Metin Uyanik, Mateo Vel\'asquez-Giraldo, Weifeng Wu, Jiaxiong Yao, and Xudong Zheng for comments on earlier versions of this paper, John Boyd for help in applying his weighted contraction mapping theorem, Ryoji Hiraguchi for extraordinary mathematical insight that improved the paper greatly, David Zervos for early guidance to the literature, and participants in a seminar at the Johns Hopkins University, a presentation at the 2009 meetings of the Society of Economic Dynamics for their insights, and at a presentation at the Australian National University.}
% \newcommand{\inframe}{https://\owner.github.io/BufferStockTheory/BufferStockTheory3.html}
% Embed metadata
\hypersetup{pdfauthor={Christopher D Carroll <[email protected]>},
pdftitle={Theoretical Foundations of Buffer Stock Saving},
pdfkeywords={Precautionary saving, buffer-stock saving, consumption, marginal propensity to consume, permanent income hypothesis, income fluctuation problem},
pdfnewwindow=true,
pdfcreator = {[email protected]}
}
\begin{document}
% Attempted to make all lines used for Web version contain {Web} (or version with only single curly brace at end) so can be removed with sed
\ifthenelse{\boolean{Web}}{ % {Web}
\renewcommand{\versn}{Web} % Too hard to figure out passing -output-directory through make4ht through htlatex, so web version is compiled with junk files in main directory
\renewcommand{\rootFromOut}{.} % {Web}
}{} % {Web}
% Tiny info header at top tracks git commit
\title{Theoretical Foundations of \\ Buffer Stock Saving}
\author{Christopher D Carroll\authNum ~and Akshay Shanker\authNum}
\keywords{Precautionary saving, buffer stock saving, marginal propensity to consume, permanent income hypothesis, income fluctuation problem}
\jelclass{D81, D91, E21 \par
\href{https://econ-ark.org}{\includegraphics{@resources/econ-ark/PoweredByEconARK}}
}
\date{\today}
% \renewcommand{\forcedate}{April 24, 2023}\date{\forcedate}
\maketitle
\hypertarget{abstract}{}
\begin{abstract}
This paper builds the foundations for a rigorous and intuitive understanding of `buffer stock' saving, behaviour that emerges in \cite{bewleyPIH}-like economies with a wealth target, pairing each theoretical result with quantitative illustrations. After describing conditions under which a consumption function exists, the paper articulates stricter `Growth Impatience' conditions that guarantee alternative forms of `target' saving --- either at the population level, or for individual consumers. Together, the numerical tools and analytical results constitute a comprehensive toolkit for understanding buffer stock models.
\end{abstract}
% Various resources
\hypertarget{links}{}
\begin{footnotesize}
\parbox{0.9\textwidth}{
\begin{center}
\begin{tabbing}
\texttt{~~~\REMARK:~} \= \= \texttt{\url{https://econ-ark.org/materials/bufferstocktheory}} \\
\texttt{Dashboard:~} \> \> \texttt{\href{https://econ-ark.org/materials/bufferstocktheory}{Click `Launch Dashboard' Button}} \\
\texttt{~~~~~html:~} \> \> \texttt{\href{https://\owner.github.io/BufferStockTheory/}{https://\owner.github.io/BufferStockTheory/}} \\ % Owner is defined in Resources/owner.tex
\texttt{~~~~~~PDF:~} \> \> \texttt{\href{https://github.com/\owner/BufferStockTheory/blob/master/BufferStockTheory.pdf}{BufferStockTheory.pdf}} \\
\texttt{~~~Slides:~} \> \> \texttt{\href{https://github.com/\owner/BufferStockTheory/blob/master/LaTeX/BufferStockTheory-Slides.pdf}{BufferStockTheory-Slides.pdf}} \\
% \texttt{~Appendix:~} \> \> \texttt{\url{https://\owner.github.io/BufferStockTheory/BufferStockTheory3.html#Appendices}} \\
\texttt{~~~GitHub:~} \> \> \texttt{\href{https://github.com/\owner/BufferStockTheory}{https://github.com/\owner/BufferStockTheory}} \\
\end{tabbing}
\end{center}
% The \href{https://econ-ark.org/materials/bufferstocktheory\?dashboard}{dashboard} lets users see consequences of alternative parameters in an interactive framework.
} % end \parbox{\textwidth}
\end{footnotesize}
\begin{authorsinfo}
\name{Contact: \href{mailto:[email protected]}{\texttt{[email protected]}}, Department of Economics, 590 Wyman Hall, Johns Hopkins University, Baltimore, MD 21218, \url{https://www.econ2.jhu.edu/people/ccarroll}, and National Bureau of Economic Research.}\name{Contact: \href{mailto:[email protected]}{\texttt{[email protected]}}, Department of Economics, University of New South Wales, Sydney, Australia and Australian Research Council (ARC) Center for Excellence in Population and Ageing Research (CEPAR).}
\end{authorsinfo}
\pagenumbering{gobble} % Prevent numbering for pages including the TOC and title page
\hypersetup{pageanchor=false} % https://tex.stackexchange.com/questions/18924/pdftex-warning-ext4-destination-with-the-same-identifier-nam-epage-1-has
\ifthenelse{\boolean{Web}}{
}{
\begin{minipage}{0.9\textwidth}
\footnotesize The paper's results \href{https://\owner.github.io/nbreproduce}{can be automatically reproduced} using the {\ARKurl} toolkit by executing the \href{https://econ-ark.org/materials/bufferstocktheory}{notebook}; for reference to the toolkit itself see \href{https://econ-ark.org/acknowledging}{Acknowleding Econ-ARK}. Thanks to the \href{https://consumerfinance.gov}{Consumer Financial Protection Bureau} for funding the original creation of the {\ARKurl} toolkit; and to the \href{https://sloan.org}{Sloan Foundation} for funding Econ-ARK's \href{https://sloan.org/grant-detail/8071}{extensive further development} that brought it to the point where it could be used for this project. The toolkit can be cited with its digital object identifier, \href{https://doi.org/10.5281/zenodo.1001067}{https://doi.org/10.5281/zenodo.1001067}, as is done in the paper's own references as \cite{carroll_et_al-proc-scipy-2018}. Thanks to Will Du, James Feigenbaum, Joseph Kaboski, Miles Kimball, Qingyin Ma, Misuzu Otsuka, Damiano Sandri, John Stachurski, David Stern, Adam Szeidl, Alexis Akira Toda, Metin Uyanik, Mateo Vel\'asquez-Giraldo, Weifeng Wu, Jiaxiong Yao, and Xudong Zheng for comments on earlier versions of this paper, John Boyd for help in applying his weighted contraction mapping theorem, Ryoji Hiraguchi for extraordinary mathematical insight that improved the paper greatly, David Zervos for early guidance to the literature, and participants in a seminar at the Johns Hopkins University, a presentation at the 2009 meetings of the Society of Economic Dynamics for their insights, and at a presentation at the Australian National University. Shanker gratefully acknowledges research support from the Australian Research Council (ARC LP190100732) and ARC Centre of Excellence in Population Ageing Research (CE17010005).
\end{minipage}
\titlepagefinish\pagebreak
\let\LaTeXStandardContentsName\contentsname
\renewcommand{\contentsname}{}
\tableofcontents
\pagebreak
\medskip\medskip
\begin{minipage}{0.9\textwidth}
\listoffigures
\end{minipage}
\medskip\medskip
\begin{minipage}{0.9\textwidth}
\listoftables
\end{minipage}
} % {Web}
\hypersetup{pageanchor=true} % https://tex.stackexchange.com/questions/18924/pdftex-warning-ext4-destination-with-the-same-identifier-nam-epage-1-has
\pagebreak
\hypertarget{Introduction}{}
\section{Introduction}\label{sec:intro}
\setcounter{page}{0}\pagenumbering{arabic}
The precautionary motive to save springs from the fact that extra resources increase a consumer's ability to buffer spending against income shocks.\footnote{\cite{CarrollKimballPSPW}.}
A consumer who, in the absence of shocks, would be `impatient' enough to want to spend down resources, will (when there are shocks to worry about) experience an intensifying precautionary motive as their buffering capacity shrinks.
If resources fall far enough, the consequence may be to make `prudence' (\cite{kimball:standardra}) strong enough to counterbalance impatience.
A consumer whose behavior is governed by this competition between impatience and prudence has been described, starting with \cite{deatonLiqConstr}, as engaging in `buffer stock saving.'
The logic of buffer stock saving underpins key findings in heterogeneous-agent (HA) macroeconomics.
For example, it can explain why, during the Great Recession, middle-class consumers cut spending more than the poor or the rich~\citep{kmpHandbook}.
Buffer stock saving also can explain why consumption growth tracks income growth over much of the life cycle \citep{carrollBSLCPIH}, rather than being determined solely by preferences and interest rates as Irving~\cite{fisherInterestTheory} proposed (and as log-linearized Euler equations erroneously suggest (\cite{carroll:death}).
Despite the central role that buffer stock saving plays in HA-macro, the literature lacks a formal theory mapping the conditions under which such behavior emerges.
This paper establishes the required foundations by explaining the circumstances under which preferences, income growth, uncertainty, and the interest rate imply the existence of buffer-stock saving `targets' both at the individual level and in the aggregate.
We formalize buffer stock saving using the Friedman-Muth(-Zeldes) income fluctuation model, incorporating realistic transitory and permanent shocks~\citep{friedmanATheory, muthOptimal, zeldesStochastic},\footnote{By which we mean, calibrated to micro empirical evidence.}
constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) utility, and a `natural borrowing constraint' of the kind first employed by \cite{zeldesStochastic}.\footnote{A natural borrowing constraint is the maximum amount a consumer will be willing to borrow under any circumstances.
See~\cite{carrollBSLCPIH} or~\cite{gpLifeCycle} for arguments that models with only `natural' constraints (see below) match a wide variety of facts; for a model with explicit constraints that produces very similar results, see, e.g.~\cite{Cagetti}.
They are analytically convenient as the consumption function becomes twice continuously differentiable and also becomes arbitrarily close (cf.\ Section~\ref{subsubsec:deatonIsLimit}) to less tractable models with artificial liquidity constraints.}\textsuperscript{,}\footnote{The model permits separate transitory and permanent shocks (\textit{a la}~\cite{muthOptimal}) and permanent growth in income, which a large empirical literature finds to be of dominant importance in microdata.
For example, MaCurdy~\citeyearpar{macurdyTimeseries}; Abowd and Card~\citeyearpar{acCovariance}; Carroll and Samwick~\citeyearpar{csNature}; Jappelli and Pistaferri~\citeyear{jpCins}; et.
seq.
Much of the literature instead incorporates highly `persistent' but not completely permanent shocks, but~\cite{dhmImproving} show that when measurement problems are handled correctly, admin data yield serial correlation coefficients $0.98-1.00$; and~\cite{dmHowMuch} suggests that survey data support the same conclusion.}
In an infinite-horizon (or a \cite{blanchardFinite} perpetual youth) version of this framework, we establish and explain the economic implications of two main results.
Our first result identifies conditions under which a real-valued and strictly positive consumption function -- a `non-degenerate limiting solution' -- exists as the terminal period of a finite horizon consumer problem becomes arbitrarily distant.
If it exists, a non-degenerate limiting solution corresponds to an infinite horizon solution found in the literature studying income fluctuation problems.
This literature, starting from \cite{bewleyPIH} and proceeding through to recent contributions by \cite{mstIncFluct,maUnboundedDP}, has imposed an artificial constraint strictly greater than the natural liquidity constraint to guarantee that the dynamic programming problem can be defined by a `compact' stationary functional operator (in the sense \hyperlink{challengesDP}{articulated below}), permitting the use of contraction mapping arguments to show existence (\cite{maUnboundedDP, stachurski2022}).
However, a natural liquidity constraint with a realistic CRRA parameter greater than one implies that value functions are unbounded below, which prevents us from characterizing a general form of the consumer's problem using a compact stationary Bellman operator.
In this context, our results establish the existence of a non-degenerate solution without the need for an artificial constraint.
We further demonstrate that the artificial case emerges as a limiting version of the natural case, bridging the two approaches.
Once we have established the existence of a non-degenerate solution, the second (and most important) result of the paper is to identify conditions under which buffer stock `targets' exist, for individual consumers or in the aggregate.
\paragraph{Consumer Patience}
In establishing our main theoretical results, an additional contribution of the paper is to formalize the relationship between consumer patience and consumer behaviour.
A key insight is that the existence of non-degenerate limiting solutions and buffer stock targets depends on the consumer's patience in relation to the rate of return ($\Rfree$) and stochastic rate of permanent income growth ($\PermGroFacRnd$).
However, while the discount factor, $\DiscFac$, has been known to represent the consumer's `pure' rate of time preference, reflecting the relative weight of utility over time, `patience' lacks a similarly clear understanding in the literature.
To grasp the notion of consumer patience, consider a perfect foresight scenario with no borrowing constraints.
In this setting, a consumer optimally balances current wealth between present and future consumption, resulting in a positive marginal propensity to consume.
For a consumer with relative risk aversion of $\CRRA$, we show the marginal propensity to save (and consume) depends on the term $\APFac\colon =(\Rfree \DiscFac)^{1/\CRRA}$, which we introduce as the consumer's \hyperlink{APFAC}{absolute patience factor}.
The \hyperlink{APFAC}{absolute patience factor} is central to understanding consumption and saving behaviour and can also be understood as the rate of consumption growth for a perfect foresight consumer with relative risk aversion of $\CRRA$.
A consumer exhibits `absolute impatience' when, absent any precautionary motives, they prefer to shift future resources to the present to increase current consumption.
This occurs when their pure rate of time preference leads them to discount the future more heavily than the interest rate incentivizes saving, specifically when $\APFac < 1$ and $(\Rfree \DiscFac) < 1$.
However, as noted by \cite{szeidlInvariant} and \cite{maUnboundedDP}, the condition $(\Rfree \DiscFac) < 1$ commonly used in the literature to guarantee stability of asset distributions, is neither necessary nor sufficient for ensuring a non-degenerate limiting solution.
In the perfect foresight case without borrowing constraints, what we show is necessary for a non-degenerate limiting solution is `return impatience': $\APFac < \Rfree$.
This condition guarantees that the consumer is not so patient that they will allocate all their wealth to the future (consuming nothing now).\footnote{This condition is \textit{not} required for a non-degenerate limiting solution when there is an artificial borrowing constraint, so long as the consumer would wish to bring future resources to the present by borrowing -- which occurs if income growth exceeds the interest rate.}
\paragraph{Solution Under Uncertainty}
The first main result of the paper shows how for a consumer facing stochastic income shocks, the condition required for nondegeneracy is (surprisingly) \textit{weaker} than the condition required for a non-degenerate solution in the perfect foresight case.
What is needed is \hyperlink{WRIC}{`weak return impatience.'}: $\pZero \APFac < \Rfree$, where $\pZero $ is the probability of a zero income shock.
If a consumer is weak return impatient, then even if their wealth barely exceeds the limits imposed by the natural borrowing constraint, they will consume enough to make their expected resources fall.
In addition to weak return impatience, we show that in the presence of permanent growth, the standard `$\DiscFac<1$' requirement must be modified to take account of income growth uncertainty; we describe the new requirement as requiring \hyperlink{FVAC}{`finite value of autarky'} (where here we think of autarky as perpetual consumption of your permanent income).
If weak return impatience and finite value of autarky are satisfied, then we show that a non-degenerate limiting solution exists.
Our method of proof uses a novel argument utilizing the upper and lower bounds of consumers' marginal propensities of consume (MPCs).
We first show the sequence of Bellman operators associated with a finite horizon problem for a given terminal period are a sequence of well-defined contraction maps.
\hyperlink{WRIC}{Weak return impatience} prevents the upper bound on the MPC from converging to zero as the terminal period recedes, which allows us to show the finite horizon value functions converge to a non-degenerate solution.
The introduction of uncertainty brings a precautionary motive that enhances the consumer's preference for saving.
So it is a surprise that in the stochastic setting, the `patience' condition required for nondegeneracy is weaker than that required for the perfect foresight unconstrained case.
The reason has to do with the other aspect of the introduction of uncertainty, which is the natural borrowing constraint imposed by the requirement that debts be repaid.
Just as in the perfect foresight case, if the consumer would want to borrow against future income that is growing faster than the rate at which it is discounted, the natural borrowing constraint does what the artificial borrowing constraint does in the perfect foresight case: It prevents too much borrowing.
\paragraph{Buffer Stock Targets}
Turning to our results on the buffer stock target, the requirement for the existence of an individual target is \hyperlink{GICMod}{`strong growth impatience,'} which prevents `normalized market resources' (the ratio of market resources to permanent income), $\mNrm$, from growing without bound.
In particular, strong growth impatience requires that as a consumer's resources grow, eventually a point will come at which the expected ratio of a consumer's \hyperlink{APFAC}{absolute patience} to the uncertainty-adjusted growth of permanent income is less than one ($\mathbb{E}\frac{\APFac}{\PermGroFacRnd}<1$).
Under the condition, as a consumer's normalized market resources approach infinity, the \textit{expected ratio} of market resources--incorporating optimal saving--to the uncertain permanent income growth factor, must eventually becomes less than one.
That is, normalized market resources eventually revert back toward a target.
A weaker requirement, \hyperlink{GIC}{`growth impatience,'} ensures the existence of an aggregate buffer stock target even when individual target ratios are unbounded.
Growth impatience requires the \textit{ratio} of \hyperlink{APFacDefn}{absolute patience} to the \textit{expected} growth factor of permanent income to be less than one ($\frac{\APFac}{\mathbb{E}\PermGroFacRnd}<1$).
But recall that at the individual level, the ratio of market resources to permanent income might grow either as a result of an increase in resources or as the result of a decrease in permanent income.
Idiosyncratic uncertainty in permanent income means that in any given year there will be a portion of consumers whose permanent income has declined.
Such consumers will experience an increase in the ratio of market resources to permanent income, even if their level of market resources has stagnated or even fallen (but by less than the decline in permanent income).
Nonetheless, under \hyperlink{GIC}{`growth impatience'}, the ratio of average market resources to average permanent income converges back to a target.
As \cite{harmenbergInvariant} points out, a stationary distribution of market resources, weighted by permanent income still exists under growth impatience.
We develop the insight by \cite{harmenbergInvariant} and demonstrate that the contribution to aggregate consumption of consumers who accumulate unbounded resources diminishes as they receive a smaller and smaller measure of permanent income.
Thus in the aggregate, even with a fixed aggregate interest rate that differs from the time preference rate, a small open economy populated by buffer stock consumers has a balanced growth path in which growth rates of consumption, income, and market resources match the exogenous growth rate of permanent income (equivalent, here, to productivity growth).
In the terms of~\cite{schmitt2003closing}, buffer stock saving is an appealing method of `closing' a small open economy, because it requires no \textit{ad-hoc} assumptions.
Not even liquidity constraints.
An interesting implication is that a non-degenerate limiting consumption function exists even when the (exogenous) growth rate of income exceeds the (exogenous) interest rate.
Many economic models impose an interest rate greater than the growth rate because if this condition does not hold then the risk-neutral present discounted value of future income is infinite.
The presence of the precautionary motive short-circuits this logic, and implies that even if \textit{in a risk-neutral sense} human wealth is unbounded as the planning horizon recedes, the limiting solution is not $c = \infty$.
Using this insight, the final section shows that for a consumer to have a non-degenerate value function in the limit as the planning horizon recedes, \hyperlink{APF}{absolute patience} cannot exceed \textit{both} market returns and the growth rate of income.
Growth impatience must hold when return impatience fails and vice-versa.
When both growth impatience and return impatience fail, the limiting consumption function is either $\cFunc(\mNrm)=0$ or $\cFunc(\mNrm)=\infty$ for all $\mNrm$.
\vspace{-1em}
\hypertarget{cfLiterature}{}
\hypertarget{DiffFromLit}{}
\paragraph{Relationship to Literature}
Buffer stock saving behaviour was recognized by \cite{friedmanATheory} and formally introduced by \cite{carrollBSLCPIH} to account for consumption and income patterns in the data.
The class of models we use to study buffer stock saving, income fluctuation problems, are now pervasive, though the foundational contributions include \cite{bewleyPIH}, \cite{imrohorogluBusinessCycles}, \cite{zeldesStochastic}, \cite{deatonLiqConstr}, \cite{huggettRiskFreeRate} and \cite{aiyagari:ge}.
Amongst this literature \cite{zeldesStochastic} was the first to calibrate a quantitatively plausible example of permanent and transitory shocks and argue that the natural borrowing constraint was a quantitatively plausible alternative to `artificial' or `ad hoc' borrowing constraints.\footnote{The same (numerical) point applies for infinite horizon models (calibrated to actual empirical data on household income dynamics); cf.~\cite{carrollBrookings}.} The natural borrowing limit was also described by \cite{aiyagari:ge}, but implications for existence not discussed.\footnote{Income fluctuation problems do not require existence of stable buffer stock targets, though such points will often exist.}
On the technical front, traditional Bellman iteration approaches to showing existence rely on bounded pay-offs~\citep{slpMethods}.\footnote{The CRRA utility function does not satisfy Bewley's assumption that $\uFunc(0)$ is well-defined, or that $\uP(0)$ is well-defined and finite.
Our framework differs from Schectman and Escudero~\citeyearpar{seIncFluct} in that they impose liquidity constraints and positive minimum income.
It differs from Deaton~\citeyearpar{deatonLiqConstr} because liquidity constraints are absent; there are separate transitory and permanent shocks (\textit{a la}~\cite{muthOptimal}); and the transitory shocks here can occasionally cause income to reach zero.
Similar restrictions are made in the well known papers by Scheinkman and Weiss~\citeyearpar{scheinkman&weiss:borrowing}, Clarida~\citep{claridaErgodic}, and others~\cite{cwcUnderUncert}.
For a related continuous-$t$ model, see~\cite{tocheUrisk}.
\cite{asHomogeneous} relaxed the bounds on the return function, but they address only the deterministic case with compact valued action sets.
\cite{mnUnique} assume a framework with compact action sets, and real-valued pay-offs, which cannot handle CRRA utility unbounded below.
See~\cite{yaoNote} for a detailed discussion of the reasons the existing literature up through~\cite{mnUnique} cannot handle the problem described here.
\@~\cite{mvExistence} provide a correction to~\cite{rrExistence}, but only addresses the deterministic case.} Overcoming these restrictions to allow unbounded pay-offs, the literature on the one hand emphasized time iteration operators defined by Euler equations ~\citep{deatonLiqConstr, lsIncFluct, mstIncFluct} and, on the other hand, transformations of the Bellman equation \citep{maUnboundedDP, rinconZapatero2024}.
The results by \cite{mstIncFluct,maUnboundedDP} are the most general we are aware of that tackle income fluctuation problems, and can be specialized to show existence in a model with the rate of return and discount factor shock structure arising from permanent and transitory shocks (once the model is normalized).
However, the cited approach impose an artificial liquidity constraint, which effectively bound utility from below, and thus cannot be applied here.
While \cite{rinconZapatero2024} allows utility to be unbounded below, the Bellman operator's feasibility correspondence is assumed to be compact, which again would require us to impose an artificial liquidity constraint.
Our approach to constructing the weighted-norm space of value functions uses results on unbounded dynamic programming by \citep{jboydWeighted}.\footnote{\cite{asHomogeneous} showed how the approach could be used to address the homogeneous case (of which CRRA is an example) in a deterministic framework; later,~\cite{duranDiscounting} showed how to extend the~\cite{jboydWeighted} approach to the stochastic case.
See also exposition by \cite{stachurski2022}, Ch.
12.} However, our use of marginal propensities to consume to construct per-period bounds on the Bellman operator is novel.
Moreover, our growth and return patience concern economic mechanisms (rather than general assumptions) that arise in the presence of permanent income uncertainty and growth.
To the best of our knowledge, these economic mechanisms have not been explored elsewhere.
Finally, our discussion on aggregate growth rates builds on \cite{szeidlInvariant} and \cite{harmenbergInvariant} who give results on the existence and convergence of stationary wealth distributions for the model presented here.
\cite{mstIncFluct} also give results on stationarity, under the restrictions mentioned above.
While conditions for stationarity resemble \hyperlink{GIC}{growth impatience} and \hyperlink{GICMod}{strong growth impatience,} our objective is to establish existence of stable buffer stock targets, which has empirical relevance, rather than prove stochastic stability.
\compilingasstandalone{
\econarkmultibib{Introduction}
}
\end{document}
% TeX-master-file: t
% eval: (setq TeX-command-list (assq-delete-all (car (assoc "BibTeX" TeX-command-list)) TeX-command-list))
% eval: (setq TeX-command-list (assq-delete-all (car (assoc "Biber" TeX-command-list)) TeX-command-list))
% eval: (add-to-list 'TeX-command-list '("BibTeX" "bibtex %s" TeX-run-BibTeX nil t :help "Run BibTeX") t)
% eval: (add-to-list 'TeX-command-list '("BibTeX" "bibtex %s" TeX-run-BibTeX nil (plain-tex-mode latex-mode doctex-mode ams-tex-mode texinfo-mode context-mode) :help "Run BibTeX") t)
% TeX-PDF-mode: t
% TeX-file-line-error: t
% TeX-debug-warnings: t